The Official Journal of the Pan-Pacific Association of Input-Output Studies (PAPAIOS)

  • Open access
  • Published: 05 June 2020

Dynamic linkages between poverty, inequality, crime, and social expenditures in a panel of 16 countries: two-step GMM estimates

  • Muhammad Khalid Anser 1 ,
  • Zahid Yousaf 2 ,
  • Abdelmohsen A. Nassani 3 ,
  • Saad M. Alotaibi 3 ,
  • Ahmad Kabbani 4 &
  • Khalid Zaman 5  

Journal of Economic Structures volume  9 , Article number:  43 ( 2020 ) Cite this article

159k Accesses

56 Citations

273 Altmetric

Metrics details

The study examines the relationship between growth–inequality–poverty (GIP) triangle and crime rate under the premises of inverted U-shaped Kuznets curve and pro-poor growth scenario in a panel of 16 diversified countries, over a period of 1990–2014. The study employed panel Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) estimator for robust inferences. The results show that there is (i) no/flat relationship between per capita income and crime rate; (ii) U-shaped relationship between poverty headcount and per capita income and (iii) inverted U-shaped relationship between income inequality and economic growth in a panel of selected countries. Income inequality and unemployment rate increases crime rate while trade openness supports to decrease crime rate. Crime rate substantially increases income inequality while health expenditures decrease poverty headcount ratio. Per capita income is influenced by high poverty incidence, whereas health expenditures and trade factor both amplify per capita income across countries. The results of pro-poor growth analysis show that though the crime rate decreases in the years 2000–2004 and 2010–2014, while the growth phase was anti-poor due to unequal distribution of income. Pro-poor education and health trickle down to the lower income strata group for the years 2010–2014, as education and health reforms considerably reduce crime rate during the time period.

1 Introduction

The study evaluated different United Nation sustainable development goals (SDGs), i.e., goals 1 and 2 (poverty reduction and hunger), goals 3 and 4 (promotion of health and education), goal 10 (reduced inequalities), and goal 16 (reduction of violence, peace and justice) to access pro-poor growth and crime reduction in a panel of 16 heterogeneous countries. The discussion of crime rate in pro-poor growth (PPG) agenda remains absent in the economic development literature, though Bourguignon ( 2000 ) stressed to reduce crime and violence by judicious income distribution; however, a very limited literature is available to emphasize the need of social safety nets for vulnerable peoples that should be included in the pro-growth policy agenda for broad-based economic growth. Kelly ( 2000 ) investigated the relationship between income inequality (INC_INEQ) and urban crime, and found that INC_INEQ is the strong predictor to influence violent crime rather than property crime, while poverty (POV) and economic growth (EG) significantly affect on property crime rather than violent crime. The policies should be developed for equitable income and sound EG for reducing POV and crime across the globe. Drèze and Khera ( 2000 ) examined the inter-district variations of intentional homicides rate (IHR) in India for the period of 1981 and found that there is no significant relationship between urbanization/poverty and murder rates, while literacy rate has a strong impact to reduce criminal violence in India. The results further indicate the lower murder rate in those districts where female to male ratio is comparatively high. The study emphasized the need to reduce crime, violence and homicides by significant growth policies for sustained EG in India. Neumayer ( 2003 ) investigated the long-run relationship between political governance, economic policies and IHR using the panel of 117 selected countries for the period of 1980–1997 and concluded that IHR can be reduce by good economic and political policies. The results specified that higher income level, good civic sense, sound EG, and higher level of democracy all are connected with the lower homicides rate in a panel of countries. The study emphasized the need to improve governance indicators in order to lowering the IHR across the globe. Jacobs and Richardson ( 2008 ) examined the interrelationship between INC_INEQ and IHR in a panel of 14 developed democracies nation and found that intentional homicides is the mounting concerns in those nations where the inequitable income distribution exists, while results further provoke the presence of young males associated with the higher murder rates in a region. The policies should be formulated caution with care while devising for judicious income distribution with demographic variables in the pro-growth agenda. Sachsida et al. ( 2010 ) found inertial effect on criminality and confirmed the positive relationship between INC_INEQ, urbanization and IHR. The study emphasized the importance of public security spending to reduce IHR in Brazil. Pridemore ( 2011 ) re-assessed the relationship between POV, INC_INEQ and IHR in a cross-national panel of US states and found POV-homicides’ linkages rather than inequality-homicides’ association. The study argued that there is substantially desire to re-assess the inequality-homicides’ linkages as it might be the misspecification of the model. Ulriksen ( 2012 ) examined the relationship between PPG, POV reduction and social security policies in the context of Botswana and found that broad-based social security policies have a significant impact to reduce POV, thus there is a strong need to include social security protections in the pro-poor growth (PPG) agenda for lowering the POV rates across the globe. Ouimet ( 2012 ) investigated the impact of socio-economic factors on IHR in a panel of 165 countries for the period 2010 and found that GIP triangle are strongly connected with the IHR for all countries, while for sub-samples, the results only support the inequality-homicides association rather than POV and EG induced IHR. The results highlighted the importance of GIP triangle to reduce IHR in a panel of selected countries.

Liu et al. ( 2013 ) investigated the relationship between national scale indicators of socio-economic and demographic factors and crime rates in 32 Mexican states and found that EG, wages and unemployment negatively affect crime rates, while increase federal police force that is helpful to reduce crime rates; however, on the other way around, higher public security expenditures are linked with the higher crime rates in Mexican states. Chu and Tusalem ( 2013 ) investigated the role of state to reduce IHR in a panel of 183 nations and found that political instability increases IHR, while anocracies is the strong predictor to influence IHR in a panel of countries. The study concluded that IHR increases in those countries where there is high level of political instability and death penalty, while the amalgamation of democratic and autocratic features lead to increased IHR. The policies should be drawn to strengthen political governance across the globe. Adeleye ( 2014 ) evaluated the different determinants of INC_INEQ in a large panel of 137 countries using the time series data from 2000 to 2012 and found that per capita income (PCI), secondary education, rule of law index and unemployment rate are the strong predictors for INC_INEQ and IHR, while INC_INEQ considerably affected IHR rate in a region. Dalberis ( 2015 ) investigated the relationship between INC_INEQ, POV and crime rates in Latin American countries and found that INC_INEQ has no significant association with the crime rate in Colombia, Brazil, Uruguay and Salvador, while poverty is the strong predictor to influence crime in Brazil, Uruguay and Salvador. The results highlighted the need for pro-poorness of growth reforms that would be helpful to lowering the crime rates in Latin American countries. Harris and Vermaak ( 2015 ) considered the relationship between expenditures’ inequality and IHRe across 52 districts of South Africa and found that while keeping other district features constant, inequality does appear as a strong dominant player to induce IHR. The rational income distribution along with broad-based EG may play a vital role to reduce IHR in South Africa. Stamatel ( 2016 ) investigated the relationship between democratic cultural values and IHR in a panel of 33 democratic countries for the period 2010 and found that democratic cultural values have a positive and negative impact of IHR in the presence of strong democratic institutions and practices. Ahmed et al. ( 2016 ) identified the different predictors of economic and natural resources in the context of Iran using the time series data from 1965–2011 and found that labor productivity, exports, capital stock and natural resources are the main predictors of EG, which altogether are important for sustained long-term growth of the country. Enamorado et al. ( 2016 ) interlinked crime rates with higher INC_INEQ using a 20-year dataset of more than 2000 Mexican municipalities and confirmed the causal relationships between the two stated factors. The results confined that drug-related crime rates largely increase up to 36% if there is one-point increment in the INC_INEQ during the specified time period. The study concludes with the fact that drug-related violent crime rates are more severe due to high proliferation of large dispersion in the labor market in terms of negative job opportunities in illegal sector. Thus, the sound policies are imperative to seize drug trafficking organizations by force for pro-equality growth. Ling et al. ( 2017 ) analyzed the role of trade openness in Malaysian life expectancy using the data from 1960 to 2014. The results show that continued EG and trade openness substantially increase life expectancy during the study time period. Further, the results established the feedback relationship between income and life expectancy in a country. The study concludes that life expectancy may increase through imported healthcare goods, which improves the quality of life of the people, thus trade liberalization policies are imperative for healthy and wealthy wellbeing.

Zaman ( 2018 ) extensively surveyed the large weighted sample of intellectuals about crime–poverty nexus and explored the number of socio-economic factors that concerned with high crime rate and POV incidence in Pakistan, including INC_INEQ, injustice, unemployment, low spending on education and health, price hikes, etc. There is a high need to increase social spending on education and health infrastructure in order to combat POV and crime rates in a given country. Imran et al. ( 2018 ) considered a time series data of US for a period of 1965–2016 and concluded that incidence of POV increases the intensity of property crime in a given country, while other controlling factors including country’s PCI and unemployment rate are not significantly associated with property crime in a country. The study concludes that property crime should be restricted by strong legislative and regulatory measures, judicious income distribution, and increasing minimum wage rate, which altogether would be helpful for the poor to reap economic benefits from PPG reforms in a country. Zaman et al. ( 2019 ) evaluated the role of education in crime reduction in a panel of 21 countries for a period of 1990–2015 and found a parabola relationship between PCI and crime rates in the presence of quality education and equitable justice across countries. The study further confirmed few other causal conceptions among the variables for making sound policy implications in the context of criminal justice. Piatkowska ( 2020 ) examined the social cost of POV in terms of increasing suicides rates, crime rates, and total violent rates in the United States and across 15 European nations during the period of 1993–2000. The results show that suicides–crime–violent rates are substantially increasing due to increase in relative POV and infant mortality rates across countries. The study argued that relative POV is the strong predictor to increase social cost of nation that needs efficient economic policies to reduce crime rates. Mukherjee ( 2019 ) discussed the role of social sustainability in achieving economic sustainability by reducing different forms of violent/crime rates through state intervention in the context of Indian economy by utilizing the data for a period of 2005–2016. The results further highlighted the need of socio-economic infrastructure development that would be helpful to provide safety nets to the poor in order to reduce crime rates in a country. Duque and McKnight ( 2019 ) presented the channel through which crime rates and legal system provide a pathway to increase INC_INEQ and POV across countries. The study further discussed and highlighted the socio-economic vulnerability that escalates through unequal distribution of income and high POV incidence, which need effective legal system to reduce crime rates. Khan et al. ( 2019a ) surveyed the Bolivian economy to assess pro-poor environmental reforms that could improve the quality of life of the poor through judicious income distribution and sustainable environmental reforms. The results conclude that services’ sector and healthcare infrastructure would be helpful to reduce POV rate and achieve PPG process at country wide. Zaman et al. ( 2020 ) surveyed the large panel of countries (i.e., 124 countries) for a period of 2010–2013 to analyze the role of INC_INEQ and EG on POV incidence across countries. The results generally favor the strong linkages among the three stated factors to support GIP triangle, which forms PPG process. The study emphasized the need to adopt some re-corrective measures in order to provide social safety nets and income distribution in order to make a growth process more pro-poor. Kousar et al. ( 2019 ) confined its finding in favor of POV reduction through managing international remittances’ receipts and financial development that would be helpful to improve the mechanism of income distribution in a country like Pakistan. The study concluded that international remittances may play a vital role to reduce POV via the mediation of financial development in a country.

The real problem is how to make EG more equitable, which is helpful to reduce POV and crime rates, and make a growth more pro-poor. The SDGs largely provoked the need to sustained economic activities, which helpful to make growth policies more poor friendly. The previous studies are widely discussed crime rates and POV reduction (see Zaman 2018 ; Khan et al. 2015 ; Heinemann and Verner 2006 ; etc.); however, a very few studies interlinked POV–crime nexus under PPG and Kuznets curve (KC) hypothesis (see Saasa 2018 ; Berens and Gelepithis 2018 , etc.). Based on the interconnections between crime, POV, and PPG, the study formulated the following research questions, i.e.,

Does crime rate negatively influenced GIP triangle, which sabotages the process of PPG?

The recent study of Khan et al. ( 2019b ) provoked the need of PPG policies to ensure sustainability agenda by including socio-economic and environmental factors in policy formulation, which gives favor to the poor as compared to the non-poor. In the similar lines, the social spending on education and healthcare infrastructure, and reforms needed to reduce labor market uncertainty in the form of lessen unemployment rate is considered the viable option for crime and POV reduction across countries (Khan et al. 2017 ). Thus, the study evaluated the question, i.e.,

To what extent social spending on education, health, and labor market are helpful to reduce crime rate, poverty, and income inequality across countries?

This question would be equally benefited to the developmental economists and policy makers to devise a healthy and wealthy policy by increasing spending on social infrastructure for pro-equality growth (Wang 2017 ). The last question is based upon non-linear formulation of crime–POV nexus where it is evaluated as a second-order coefficient to check the parabola relationship between them, i.e.,

Does crime and poverty exhibit a parabola relationship between them?

The question is all about the second-order condition, which confirmed one out of three conditions, i.e., either it is accepted an inverted U-shaped or U-shaped or flat relationship between them. The second-order condition assessed the probability to reduce crime rates and incidence of POV in policy formulation.

In the light of SDGs, the study explored the impact of GIP triangle and crime rates on pro-growth and PPG policies, which is imperative for sustainable development across countries. The study added social expenditures in PPG dynamics to promote healthy and wealthy economic activities, which improves quality of life of the poor and helpful to reduce crime incidence across countries. The study is first in nature, as authors’ knowledge, which included GIP triangle and crime rate in PPG framework, while controlling different socio-economic factors, including education and health expenditures, unemployment rate, and trade openness. Further, an empirical contribution of the study is to include second-order coefficient of PCI for evaluating crime- and inequality-induced KC, while the study proceed to analyze forecast relationship between the crime and POV incidence over a next 10-year time period. Finally, the study estimated PPG index while including crime rate as a main predictor factor in GIP triangle for robust policy inferences. Thus, these objectives are achieved by different statistical techniques for robust analysis.

2 Data source and methodological framework

The study used number of promising socio-economic variables to determine the dynamic relationship between PPG factors and crime rate under the framework of an inverted U-shaped KC in a panel of 16 diversified countries, using system GMM estimator for the period of 1990–2014. The study used the following variables, i.e., crime rate (proxy by intentional homicides rate per 100,000 population), GINI index measures income inequality, poverty headcount ratio at $1.90 a day (2011 PPP) (% of total population), national estimates of unemployment in % of total labor force, education expenditures as % of GDP, per capita health expenditure in current US$, per capita income in constant 2005 US$, and trade openness as % of GDP. The samples of countries are presented in Table  7 in Appendix for ready reference. The data for the study are obtained from World Development Indicators published by World Bank ( 2015 ).

These countries are selected because of the devastating crime rate during the study time period. The recorded figures for Argentina crime rates about to 245% increase between the period of 1991 and 2007, while 2002 is considered the highest committed crime data recorded when the POV and INC_INEQ reached at their peak levels (Bouzat 2010 ). Brazil economy is working out for reduction of crime by focusing on three-point agenda, i.e., reduction in income disparity, to increase spending on education via an increase in enrollment of school dropout children, and to improve labor market conditionings. These three policies design to deter the crime rates in a given country (World Bank 2013 ). The robbery complaints largely increase since last two decades in Chile, which is being planned by controlling two action strategies, i.e., plan cuadrante and country security plan. Both the plan designed to restructured police force to reduce robbery and violence in a country (Vergara 2012 ). The rural China is suffered by high INC_INEQ that leads to higher crime rate (South China Monitoring Report 2015 ) while POV and INC_INEQ lead to crime and violent factor in Colombia (Gordon 2016 ). The socio-economic factors including low provision of education, health, high POV, and food challenges lead to increase crime in Indonesia (Pane 2017 ), while generating employment opportunities and increasing wage rate in Malaysia may be beneficial to reduce crime–POV nexus in a given country (Mulok et al. 2017 ). Mexican economy is suffered with high rate of homicides that negatively affect labor market outcomes, while country inhibits by increasing strict laws to diminish violence (Kato Vidal 2015 ). The safety situation in Morocco is cumbersome, as one of the country reports shows that an increased rate in crime is about to increase up to 23% in 2016 (OSAC 2017 ). The number of other factors remains visible in selected sample of panel of countries, including rural POV and social exclusion that is considered the main factor of socio-economic crisis in Poland (European Commission 2008 ); POV, unemployment, and INC_INEQ chiefly attributed to crime rate in South Africa (Bhorat et al. 2017 ); politics, democracy, and INC_INEQ arise conflicts in Thailand (Hewison 2014 ); corruption and high unemployment are the major conflicts in Tunisia (Saleh 2011 ); and Uruguay economy needs policy actions to reduce POV by investment in children education, modernizing rural sector, and balancing the gender gap (Thamma 2017 ). Thus, these facts about crime and POV in different countries put a focus to study crime–POV nexus under PPG framework in this study for robust evaluation. Figure  2 in Appendix shows the plots of the studied variables at level.

The study used the following non-linear equations to determine the dynamic relationship between PPG factors and crime rate in a panel of countries, i.e.,

where GDPPC indicates per capita GDP, GDPPC 2 indicates square of per capita GDP, GINI indicates Gini coefficient—income inequality, EDUEXP indicates education expenditures, HEXP indicates health expenditures, POVHCR indicates poverty headcount ratio, TOP indicates trade openness, UNEMP indicates unemployment, and CRIME indicates crime rate.

Equations ( 1 ) to ( 3 ) assessed the possible inverted U-shaped relationships between crime rate and PCI, between POVHCR and PCI, and between GINI and PCI, while Eq. ( 4 ) reviewed the PPG reforms across countries. Arellano and Bond ( 1991 ) developed the differenced GMM estimator, whom argued that the GMM estimator eliminates country effects and controls the possible endogeneity of explanatory variables using the appropriate instrumental list that evaluated by Sargan–Hansen test. The process further involves two-step GMM iterations with the time updated weights and adopted the weighting matrix by White period. The tests for autocorrelations by AR(1) and AR(2) and the Sargan test by Sargan–Hansen of over-identifying restrictions are presented for statistical reliability of the given models. The differenced GMM is superior to the 2SLS and system GMM, i.e., 2SLS regression estimator is used when the known endogeneity exists between the variables, which are handled by including the list of instrumental variables at their first lagged. Thus, the possible endogeneity problem is resolved accordingly. The system GMM further be used instead of 2SLS as if there are more than one endogenous issues exist in the model, which is unable to resolve through 2SLS estimator. Finally, the differenced GMM estimator is used as its estimated AR(1) and AR(2) bound values that would be helpful to encounter the issues of serial correlation and endogeneity problem accordingly.

Using the GMM estimator, the study verified different possibilities of KC, i.e., if the signs and magnitudes of \(\beta_{1} > 0\) and \(\beta_{2} < 0\) , than we may confirm the crime-induced KC, poverty-induced KC, and inequality-induced KC. The inverted U-shaped relationship between crime rate and PCI verified ‘crime-induced KC’, between POVHCR and PCI verified ‘POV-induced KC’, and inverted U-shaped relationship between GINI and PCI verified ‘inequality-induced KC’. On the other way around, if \(\beta_{1} < 0\) and \(\beta_{2} > 0\) , then we consider the U-shaped KC between crime rate and PCI, between POV and PCI, and between GINI and PCI, respectively. There are three other situations we may observe with the sign and magnitude of \(\beta_{1}\) and \(\beta_{2}\) , i.e., (i) \(\beta_{1} < 0\) and \(\beta_{2} = 0\) , (ii) \(\beta_{1} > 0\) and \(\beta_{2} = 0\) , and (iii) \(\beta_{1} = 0\) and \(\beta_{2} = 0\) , referred the monotonically decreasing function, monotonically increasing function, and flat/no relationship with the crime-PCI, poverty-PCI, and inequality-PCI in a panel of cross-sectional countries. The study further employed social accounting matrix by impulse response function (IRF) and variance decomposition analysis (VDA) in an inter-temporal relationship between the studied variables for a next 10-year period starting from 2015 to 2024. As it name implies, VDA explains the proportional variance in one variable caused by the proportional variance by the other variables in a vector autoregressive (VAR) system, while IRF traces the dynamic responses of a variable to innovations in other variables in the system. Both the techniques use the moving average representation of the original VAR system. Figure  1 shows the theoretical framework of the study to clearly outline the possible relationship between the stated variables.

figure 1

Source: authors’ extraction

Research framework of the study.

Figure  1 shows the possible relationship between POV and crime rates in mediation of inequality, unemployment, and EG across countries. It is likelihood that POV increases inequality that leads to decrease in EG. The low-income growth further leads to increased unemployment, which causes high crime rates. This nexus is still rotated through crime rates that increase POV incidence across countries. The PPG process still works under the stated factors that need judicious income distribution to reduce crime rates.

The study further proceeds to evaluate the PPG reforms in a panel of selected countries. Kakwani and Pernia ( 2000 ) proposed an index of PPG called ‘PPG index’, which is evaluated by the growth elasticity and inequality elasticity with respect to POV. The same methodology is adopted in this study to assess the PPG and/or pro-rich growth reforms to assess the changes in the crime rate in a panel of countries. PPG defined as a state in which where the growth trickles down to the poor as compared to the non-poor. Poverty is largely affected by two main factors, i.e., higher growth rate may reduce the POV rates, while higher INC_INEQ reduces the impact of EG to reduce POV; therefore, the PPG index included the following mathematical illustrations, i.e.,

The study further assessed the pro-poorness of social expenditures and evaluates its impact to observe changes in IHR. The study shows the following mathematical illustrations that is extended from the scholarly work of Zaman and Khilji ( 2014 ); Kakwani and Pernia ( 2000 ) and Kakwani and Son ( 2004 ) i.e.,

where \(\alpha =\) 0, 1 and 2 indicate POVHCR, poverty gap and squared poverty gap, respectively, ‘P’ indicates FGT poverty measures, and ‘SOCIALEXP’ indicates social expenditures. Differentiating \(\eta_{\alpha }\) in Eq. ( 9 ) with respect to social expenditures gives more elaborated form of GEP, i.e.,

The elasticity of entire class of poverty measures \(P_{\alpha }\) with respect to Gini index is given by

which will be always positive only when \(S{\text{OCIALEXPE}} > z\) .Equations ( 10 ) and ( 11 ) are combined together to form TPE for all FGT poverty measures, i.e.,

or \(\delta_{\alpha } = \eta_{\alpha } + \xi_{\alpha }\) . Finally, pro-poorness of social expenditures estimated based on the following equation, i.e.,

Kakwani and Son ( 2004 ) presented the following bench mark applications to assess the pro-poor and/or anti-poor policies, i.e., the following value judgments regarding the PPG index ( \(\varphi\) ) are as follows, i.e.,

\(\varphi\)  < 0, growth is pro-rich or anti-poor,

0 <  \(\varphi\) \(\le\) 0.33, the process of PPG is considerable low,

0.33 <  \(\theta\) \(\le\) 0.66, the process of PPG is moderate,

0.66 <  \(\varphi\)  < 1.0, the process of EG considered as pro-poor, and

\(\varphi \ge\) 1.0, the process of EG is highly pro-poor.

The study utilized the PPG model for ready reference in this study.

This section presented the descriptive statistics in Table  1 , correlation matrix in Table  2 , dynamic system GMM estimates in Table  3 , IRF estimates in Table  4 , VDA estimates in Table  5 , while finally Table  6 shows the estimates for PPG in a panel of selected countries. Table  1 shows that GDPPC has a minimum value of US$ 199.350 and the maximum value of US$ 11257.600, with a mean and standard deviation (STD) value of US$ 4340.777 and US$ 2490.554, respectively. GINI has a minimum value of 25% and the maximum value of 64.790%, having an STD value of 8.580% with an average value of 45.095%. The minimum value of EDUEXP is about 0.998% of GDP and the maximum value of 7.657% of GDP, with an average value of 4.051% of GDP. The average value of HEXP per capita is about US$ 321.249 and a maximum value of US$ 1431.154, with an STD value of US$ 292.802. The maximum value of POVHCR is about 69% at US$1.90 a day with an average value of 12.394% at US$1.90 a day. The minimum value of trade is 13.753% of GDP and the maximum value of 220.407% of GDP, with an average value of 62.391% of GDP. The mean value for UNEMP is about 8.890% of total labor force with STD value of 6.010%. Finally, the minimum value of crime rate is about 0.439 per 100,000 inhabitants and the maximum value of 71.786 per 100,000 inhabitants, with an average value of 11.664 per 100,000 peoples. This exercise would be helpful to understand the basic descriptions of the studied variables in a panel of countries.

Figure  3 in Appendix shows the plots of the studied variables and found the stationary movement in the variables at their first difference. Table  2 presents the estimates of correlation matrix and found that GINI (i.e., r  = 0.264), EDUEXP ( r  = 0.243), HEXP ( r  = 0.730), TOP ( r  = 0.061), UNEMP (0.152) and CRIME ( r  = 0.031) have a positive correlation with the GDPPC, while POVHCR ( r  = − 0.599) significantly decreases GDPPC.

The results further reveal that GINI is affected by EDUEXP, HEXP, UNEMP and CRIME, while it considerably decreases by trade liberalization policies. EDUEXP, HEXP, PCI, TOP and UNEMP significantly decrease POVHCR, while crime rate has a positive correlation with the POVHCR. Finally, GINI have a greater magnitude, i.e., r  = 0.671, to influence CRIME, followed by UNEMP ( r  = 0.417), EDUEXP ( r  = 0.188), and POVHCR ( r  = 0.164) while trade liberalization policies support to decrease crime rates in a panel of countries. The study now proceeds to estimate the two-step system GMM for analyzing the functional relationship between socio-economic factors and crime rate. The results are presented in Table  3 .

The results of panel GMM show that GINI and UNEMP both have a significant and direct relationship with the CRIME, while TOP have an indirect relationship with CRIME in a panel of countries. The results imply that GINI and UNEMP are the main factors that increase CRIME, while trade liberalization policies have a supportive role to decrease crime rates across countries. Thorbecke and Charumilind ( 2002 ) evaluated the impact of income inequality on health, education, political conflict, and crime, and surveyed the different casual mechanism in between income inequality and its socio-economic impact across the globe. The policies have devised while reaching the conclusive relationships between them. Kennedy et al. ( 1998 ) concluded that social capital and income inequality are the powerful predictors of intentional homicides rate and violent crime in the US states. Altindag ( 2012 ) explored the long-run relationship between unemployment and crime rates in a country-specific panel dataset of Europe and found that unemployment significantly increases crime rates, while unemployment has a power predictor of exchange rate movements and industrial accident across the Europe. Menezes et al. ( 2013 ) confirmed the positive association between income inequality and criminality, as rational income distribution tends to decrease neighborhood homicides rate while it implies an increase in the intentional homicides rate in the surrounding neighborhoods.

In a second regression panel, the results confirmed the U-shaped relationship between POVHCR and GDPPC, as at initial level of EG, POV significantly declines, while at the later stages, this result is evaporated, as EG subsequently increases POVHCR that shows pro-rich federal policies across countries. The HEXP, however, significantly decreases POVHCR during the study time period. Dercon et al. ( 2012 ) investigated the relationship between chronic POV and rural EG in Ethiopia and argued that chronic POV is associated with the lack of education, physical assets and remoteness, while EG in terms of provide better roads and extension services may trickle down to the poor in a same way that the non-chronically poor benefited. Solinger and Hu ( 2012 ) examined the relationship between health, wealth and POV in urban China and found that wealthier cities prefer to allocate their considerable portion of savings for social assistance funds, while poorer places save the city money and work outside in a hope that the peoples would be better able to support themselves. Fosu ( 2015 ) examined the relationship between GIP triangle in sub-Saharan African countries and found that as a whole, South African countries lag behind the BICR (Brazil, India, China and Russia) group of countries; however, many of them in sub-Saharan African countries have outperformed India. The results further specified that PCI is the main predictor to reduce POV in sub-Saharan African countries; however, rational income distribution is a crucial challenge to reduce POV reduction through substantial growth reforms in a region. Kalichman et al. ( 2015 ) concluded that food poverty is associated with the multifaceted problems of health-related outcomes across the globe.

In a third regression panel, the results confirm an inverted U-shaped relationship between GDPPC and GINI that verified an inequality-induced KC in a panel of countries. The results imply that at initial level of economic development, GINI first increases and then decreases with the increased GDPPC across countries. CRIME, however, it is associated with the higher GINI during the studied time period. Kuznets ( 1955 ), Ahluwalia ( 1976 ), Deininger and Squire ( 1998 ), and others confirmed an inverted U-shaped relationship between INC_INEQ and PCI in different economic settings. Mo ( 2000 ) suggested different channelss to examine the possible impact of INC_INEQ on EG and found that ‘transfer channel’ exert the most important channel, while ‘human capital’ is the least important channel that negatively affects the rate of EG via INC_INEQ. Popa ( 2012 ) argued that health and education both are important predictors for EG, while POV and unemployment negatively correlated with the EG in Romania. Herzer and Vollmer ( 2012 ) confirmed the negative relationship between INC_INEQ and EG within the sample of developing countries, developed countries, democracies, non-democracies, and sample as a whole. In a similar line, Malinen ( 2012 ) confirmed the long-run equilibrium relationship between PCI and INC_INEQ and found that income inequality negatively affected the growth of developed countries.

The final regression shows that HEXP and TOP both significantly increase GDPPC, while POVHCR decreases the pace of EG, which merely be shown pro-rich federal policies in a panel of countries. Ranis et al. ( 2000 ) found that both the health and education expenditures lead to increased EG, while investment improves human development in a cross-country regression. Bloom et al. ( 2004 ) confirmed the positive connection between health and EG across the globe. Gyimah-Brempong and Wilson ( 2004 ) examined the possible effect of healthy human capital on PCI of sub-Saharan African and OECD countries and found the positive association between them in a panel of countries.

The statistical tests of the system GMM estimator confirmed the stability of the model by F-statistics, as empirically model is stable at 1% level of confidence interval. Sargan–Hansen test confirmed the instrumental validity at conventional levels for all cases estimated. Autocorrelations tests imply that except POVHCR model, the remaining three models including CRIME, GINI and GDPPC model confirmed the absence of first- and second-order serial correlation, and as a consequence, we verified our instruments are valid. As far as POVHCR model, we believed the results of Sargan–Hansen test of over identifying restrictions and AR(1) that is insignificant at 5% level, and confirmed the validity of instruments and absence of autocorrelation at first-order serial correlation. Table  4 shows the estimate of IRF for the next 10-year period starting from a year of 2015 to 2024.

The results show that the socio-economic factors have a mix result with the rate of crime, as POVHCR slightly increases with decreasing rate with the crime data, i.e., in the next coming years from 2016, 2018, 2019, and 2022, POVHCR exhibits a negative sign, while in the remaining years in between from 2015 to 2024, POVHCR increases crime rate. GINI will considerably increase crime rate from 2022 to 2024. UNEMP has a mixed result to either increase crime rate in one period while in the very next upcoming periods, it declines crime rate. Similar types of results been found with EDUEXP, HEXP and with the TOP; however, GDPPC will constantly increase the rate of crime in a panel of countries. In an inter-temporal relationship between POVHCR and other predictors, the results show that GDPPC would significantly decrease POVHCR for the next 10-year period; however, UNEMP, HEXP, and crime rate would considerably increase POVHCR. EDUEXP and TOP would support to reduce GINI for the next upcoming years, while remaining variables including crime rate, POV, UNEMP, HEXP, and GDPPC associated with an increased GINI across countries. The GDPPC will be influenced by crime rate, POVHCR, GINI, UNEMP, HEXP, and EDUEXP, while TOP would considerably to support GDPPC for the next 10-year time period. Figure  4 in Appendix shows the IRF estimates for the ready reference.

Table  5 shows the estimates of VDA and found that POVHCR will exert the largest share to influence crime rates, followed by GDPPC, TOP, HEXP, EDUEXP, GINI, and UNEMP. POVHCR would be affected by crime rate (i.e., 4.450%), UNEMP (1.751%), GDPPC (1.120%), GINI (1.043%), HEXP (0.639%), and EDUEXP (0.512%), and TOP (0.299%), respectively.

The results further reveal that GINI will affected by POVHCR, as it is explained by 7.680% variations to influence GINI for the next 10-year period. UNEMP, EDUEXP, and crime rate will subsequently influenced GDPPC about to 1.107%, 0.965%, and 0.312% respectively. The largest variance to explain UNEMP will be TOP, while the lowest variance to influence UNEMP will be GINI for the next 10-year period. Finally, GDPPC would largely influenced by HEXP, followed by UNEMP, CRIME, POVHCR, EDUEXP, TOP, and GINI for the period of 2015 to 2024. Figure  5 in Appendix shows the plots of the VDA for ready reference.

Finally, Table  6 presents the changes in crime rate by five different growth phases, i.e., phase 1: 1990–1994, phase 2: 1995–1999, phase 3: 2000–2004, phase 4: 2005–2009, and phase 5: 2010–2014. The results show that in the years 1990–1994, 1% increase in EG and INC_INEQ decrease POVHCR by − 0.023% and − 0.630%, which reduces TPE by − 0.629 percentage points. The PPG index surpassed the bench mark value of unity and confirmed the trickledown effect that facilitates the poor as compared to the non-poor. However, there is an overwhelming increase in the crime rate beside that the pro-poorness of EG, which indicate the need for substantial safety nets’ protection to the poor that escape out from this acute activities (Wang et al. 2017 ). In a second phase from 1995 to 1999, although EG decreases POVHCR by − 0.187; however, GINI has a greater share to increase POVHCR by 0.517% that ultimately increases TPE by 0.330%. This increase in the TPE turns to decrease PPG as 1.764, which shows anti-poor/pro-rich federal policies and low reforms for the poor that accompanied with the higher rates of crime in a panel of countries. The rest of the growth phases from 2000 to 2014 show anti-poor growth accompanied with the higher INC_INEQ and lower EG; however, crime rate decreases in the year 2000–2004 and 2010–2014 besides that the growth process is anti-poor across countries. The policies should be formulated in a way to aligned crime rate with the PPG reforms across countries (Vellala et al. 2018 ).

The results of PPE index confirmed an anti-poor growth from 1990 to 2004, while at the subsequent years from 2005 to 2014, education growth rate subsequently benefited the poor as compared to the non-poor, i.e., PPE index exceeds the bench mark value of unity. Crime rate is increasing from 1990 to 1999, and from 2005 to 2009, while it decreases the crime rate for the years 2000–2004 and 2010–2014. The good sign of recovery has been visible for the years 2010–2014 where the PPE growth supports to decrease crime rate in a panel of selected countries. Finally, the PPH index confirmed two PPG phases, i.e., from 1990 to 1994, and 2010 to 2014 in which crime rate increases for the former years and decreases in the later years. The remaining health phases from 1995 to 2009 show anti-poor health index, while crime rate is still increasing during the years from 1995 to 1999 and 2005 to 2009, and decreasing for the period 2000–2004. The results emphasized the need to integrate PPG index with the crime rate, as PPG reforms are helpful to reduce humans’ costs by increasing EG and social expenditures, and providing judicious income distribution to escape out from POV and vulnerability across the globe (Musavengane et al. 2019 ).

From the overall results, we come to the conclusion that social spending on education and health is imperative to reduce crime incidence, while it further translated a positive impact on POV and inequality reduction across countries (Hinton 2016 ). EG is a vital factor to reduce POV; however, it is not a sufficient condition under higher INC_INEQ (Dudzevičiūtė and Prakapienė 2018 ). INC_INEQ and unemployment rate both are negatively correlated with crime rates; however, it may be reduced by judicious income distribution and increases social spending across countries (Costantini et al. 2018 ). Trade liberalization policies reduce incidence of crime rates and improve country’s PCI, which enforce the need to capitalize domestic exports by expanding local industries. Thus, the United Nations SDGs would be achieved by its implication in the countries perspectives (Dix-Carneiro et al. 2018 ). The study achieved the research objectives by its theoretical and empirical contribution, which seems challenge for the developmental experts to devise policies toward more pro-growth and PPG.

4 Conclusions and policy recommendations

This study investigated the dynamic relationship between socio-economic factors and crime rate to assess PPG reforms for reducing crime rate in a panel of 16 diversified countries, using a time series data from 1990–2014. The study used PCI and square PCI in relation with crime rate, POVHCR, and GINI to evaluate crime-induced KC, poverty-induced KC and inequality-induced KC, while PPG index assesses the federal growth reforms regarding healthcare provision, education and wealth to escape out from POV and violence. The results show that GINI and UNEMP are the main predictors that have a devastating impact to increase crime rate. Trade liberalization policies are helpful to reduce crime rate and increase PCI. Healthcare expenditures decrease POVHCR and amplify EG. The EG is affected by POVHCR, which requires strong policy framework to devise PPG approach in a panel of selected countries. The study failed to establish crime-induced KC and poverty-induced KC, while the study confirmed an inequality-induced KC. The results of IRF reveal that PCI would considerably increase crime rate, while crime rate influenced GINI and PCI for the next 10-year period. The estimates of VDA show that POVHCR explained the greater share to influence crime rates, while reverse is true in case of POVHCR. The study divided the studied time period into five growth phases 1990–1994, 1995–1999, 2000–2004, 2005–2009, and 2010–2014 to assess PPG, PPH, and PPE reforms and observe the changes in crime rates. The results show that there is an only period from 1990 to 1994 that shows PPG, while crime rate is still increasing in that period; however, in the years 2000–2004, and 2010–2014, crime rate decreases without favoring the growth to the poor. PPE and PPH assessment confirmed the reduction in the crime rates for the years 2010–2014. The overall results confirmed the strong correlation between socio-economic factors and crime rates to purse the pro-poorness of government policies across countries. The overall results emphasized the need of strong policy framework to aligned PPG policies with the reduction in crime rate across the globe. The study proposed the following policy recommendations, i.e.,

Education, health and wealth are the strong predictors of reducing crime rates and achieving PPG, thus it should be aligned with inclusive trade policies to reduce human cost in terms of decreasing chronic poverty and violence/crime.

The policies should be formulated to strengthen the pro-poorness of social expenditures that would be helpful to reduce an overwhelming impact of crime rate in a panel of countries.

GIP triangle is mostly viewed as a pro-poor package to reduce the vicious cycle of poverty; however, there is a strong need to include some other social factors including unemployment, violence, crime, etc., which is mostly charged due to increase in poverty and unequal distribution of income across the globe. The policies should devise to observe the positive change in lessen the crime rate by PPG reforms in a panel of selected countries.

The significant implication of the Kuznets’ work should be extended to the some other unexplored factors especially for crime rate that would be traced out by the pro-poor agenda and pro-growth reforms.

There is a need to align the positivity of judicious income distribution with the broad-based economic growth that would be helpful to reduce poverty and crime rate across countries.

The result although not supported the ‘parabola’ relationship between income and crime rates; however, it confirmed the U-shaped relationship between income and poverty. The economic implication is that income is not the sole contributor to increase crime rates while poverty exacerbates violent crimes across countries. There is a high need to develop a mechanism through which poverty incidence can be reduced, which would ultimately lead to decreased crime rates. The improvement in the labor market structure, judicious income distribution, and providing social safety nets are the desirable strategies to reduce crime rates and poverty incidence across countries, and

The results supported parabola relationship between economic growth and inequality, which gives a clear indication to improve income distribution channel for reducing poverty and crime rates at global scale.

These seven policies would give strong alignment to improve social infrastructure for managing crime through equitable justice and PPG process.

Availability of data and materials

The data are freely available on World Development Indicator, published by World Bank on given URL ID: https://datacatalog.worldbank.org/dataset/world-development-indicators .

Adeleye NB (2014). The determinants of income inequality and the relationship to crime. Unpublished dissertation, University of Sussex, UK. https://www.researchgate.net/profile/Ngozi_Adeleye2/publication/276410308_The_Determinants_of_Income_Inequality_and_the_Relationship_to_Crime/links/5558c9f808aeaaff3bf98a45.pdf . Accessed 6 Jan 2016

Ahluwalia MS (1976) Income distribution and development: some stylized facts. Am Econ Rev 66(2):128–135

Google Scholar  

Ahmed K, Mahalik MK, Shahbaz M (2016) Dynamics between economic growth, labor, capital and natural resource abundance in Iran: an application of the combined cointegration approach. Res Policy 49:213–221

Article   Google Scholar  

Altindag DT (2012) Crime and unemployment: evidence from Europe. Int Rev Law Econ 32(1):145–157

Arellano M, Bond SR (1991) Some tests of specification of panel data: monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–297

Berens S, Gelepithis M (2018) Welfare state structure, inequality, and public attitudes towards progressive taxation. Socio Econ Rev. https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwx063

Bhorat H, Thornton A, Van der Zee K (2017). Socio-economic determinants of crime in South Africa: an empirical assessment. DPRU Working Paper 201704. DPRU, University of Cape Town, Rondebosch

Bloom DE, Canning D, Sevilla J (2004) The effect of health on economic growth: a production function approach. World Dev 32(1):1–13

Bourguignon F (2000). Crime, violence and inequitable development. Annual World Bank Conference on development economics 1999, pp. 199–220

Bouzat G (2010) Inequality, crime, and security in Argentina. SELA (Seminario en Latinoamérica de Teoría Constitucional y Política) Papers. Paper 91. http://digitalcommons.law.yale.edu/yls_sela/91 . Accessed 6 October 2018

Chu DC, Tusalem RF (2013) The role of the state on cross-national homicide rates. Int Crim Justice Rev 23(3):252–279

Costantini M, Meco I, Paradiso A (2018) Do inequality, unemployment and deterrence affect crime over the long run? Reg Stud 52(4):558–571

Dalberis R (2015). Extreme levels of poverty and inequality may lead to equally high levels of social conflict and crime. Unpublished dissertation, CUNY Academic Works, New York. http://academicworks.cuny.edu/cc_etds_theses/346/ . Accessed 6 Jan 2016

Deininger K, Squire L (1998) New ways of looking at old issues: inequality and growth. J Dev Econ 57(2):259–287

Dercon S, Hoddinott J, Woldehanna T (2012) Growth and chronic poverty: evidence from rural communities in Ethiopia. J Dev Stud 48(2):238–253

Dix-Carneiro R, Soares RR, Ulyssea G (2018) Economic shocks and crime: evidence from the Brazilian trade liberalization. Am Econ J Appl Econ 10(4):158–195

Dreze J, Khera R (2000) Crime, gender, and society in India: insights from homicide data. Popul Dev Rev 26(2):335–352

Dudzevičiūtė G, Prakapienė D (2018) Investigation of the economic growth, poverty and inequality inter-linkages in the European Union countries. J Secur Sust Issues 7:839–854

Duque M, McKnight A (2019) Understanding the relationship between inequalities and poverty: mechanisms associated with crime, the legal system and punitive sanctions. LIP Paper, 6, CASE/215, Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, London School of Economics, London, UK. http://sticerd.lse.ac.uk/dps/case/cp/casepaper215.pdf . Accessed 8 March 2020

Enamorado T, López-Calva LF, Rodríguez-Castelán C, Winkler H (2016) Income inequality and violent crime: evidence from Mexico’s drug war. J Dev Econ 120:128–143

European Commission (2008 ). Poverty and social exclusion in rural areas—final report Annex I—Country Studies-Poland. European commission, Brussels

Fosu AK (2015) Growth, inequality and poverty in Sub-Saharan Africa: recent progress in a global context. Oxford Dev Stud 43(1):44–59

Gordon E (2016) Poverty, crime, and conflicts: socio-economic inequalities and prospects for peace in Colombia. Centre for security governance. http://secgovcentre.org/2016/10/poverty-crime-and-conflict-socio-economic-inequalities-and-the-prospects-for-peace-in-colombia/ . Accessed 6 October 2018

Gyimah-Brempong K, Wilson M (2004) Health human capital and economic growth in Sub-Saharan African and OECD countries. Q Rev Econ Finance 44(2):296–320

Harris G, Vermaak C (2015) Economic inequality as a source of interpersonal violence: evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa and South Africa. South Afr J Econ Manag Sci 18(1):45–57

Heinemann, Verner D (2006) Crime and violence in development: a literature review of Latin America and the Caribbean. The World Bank, Policy Research Working Papers, Washington D.C

Herzer D, Vollmer S (2012) Inequality and growth: evidence from panel cointegration. J Econ Inequality 10(4):489–503

Hewison K (2014) Considerations on inequality and politics in Thailand. Democratization 21(5):846–866

Hinton E (2016) From the war on poverty to the war on crime: the making of mass incarceration in America. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

Book   Google Scholar  

Imran M, Hosen M, Chowdhury MAF (2018) Does poverty lead to crime? Evidence from the United States of America. Int J Soc Econ 45(10):1424–1438

Jacobs D, Richardson AM (2008) Economic inequality and homicide in the developed nations from 1975 to 1995. Homicide Stud 12(1):28–45

Kakwani N, Pernia EM (2000) What is pro-poor growth? Asian Dev Rev 18(1):1–16

Kakwani N, Son HH (2004) Pro-poor growth: concepts and measurement with country case studies. Pakistan Dev Rev 42(4 Part I):417–444

Kalichman SC, Hernandez D, Kegler C, Cherry C, Kalichman MO, Grebler T (2015) Dimensions of poverty and health outcomes among people living with HIV infection: limited resources and competing needs. J Community Health 40(4):702–708

Kato Vidal EL (2015) Violence in Mexico: an economic rationale of crime and its impacts. EconoQuantum 12(2):93–108

Kelly M (2000) Inequality and crime. Rev Econ Stat 82(4):530–539

Kennedy BP, Kawachi I, Prothrow-Stith D, Lochner K, Gupta V (1998) Social capital, income inequality, and firearm violent crime. Soc Sci Med 47(1):7–17

Khan N, Ahmed J, Nawaz M, Zaman K (2015) The socio-economic determinants of crime in Pakistan: new evidence on an old debate. Arab Econ Business J 10(2):73–81

Khan HUR, Khan A, Zaman K, Nabi AA, Hishan SS, Islam T (2017) Gender discrimination in education, health, and labour market: a voice for equality. Qual Quant 51(5):2245–2266

Khan HUR, Zaman K, Yousaf SU, Shoukry AM, Gani S, Sharkawy MA (2019a) Socio-economic and environmental factors influenced pro-poor growth process: new development triangle. Environ Sci Pollut Res 26(28):29157–29172

Khan HUR, Nassani AA, Aldakhil AM, Abro MMQ, Islam T, Zaman K (2019b) Pro-poor growth and sustainable development framework: evidence from two step GMM estimator. J Cleaner Prod 206:767–784

Kousar R, Rais SI, Mansoor A, Zaman K, Shah STH, Ejaz S (2019) The impact of foreign remittances and financial development on poverty and income inequality in Pakistan: evidence from ARDL-bounds testing approach. J Asian Finance Econ Business 6(1):71–81

Kuznets S (1955) Economic growth and income inequality. Am Econ Rev 45(1):1–28

Ling CH, Ahmed K, Muhamad R, Shahbaz M, Loganathan N (2017) Testing the social cost of rapid economic development in Malaysia: the effect of trade on life expectancy. Soc Indic Res 130(3):1005–1023

Liu Y, Fullerton TM, Ashby NJ (2013) Assessing the impacts of labor market and deterrence variables on crime rates in Mexico. Contemp Econ Policy 31(4):669–690

Malinen T (2012) Estimating the long-run relationship between income inequality and economic development. Empirical Econ 42(1):209–233

Menezes T, Silveira-Neto R, Monteiro C, Ratton JL (2013) Spatial correlation between homicide rates and inequality: evidence from urban neighborhoods. Econ Lett 120(1):97–99

Mo PH (2000) Income inequality and economic growth. Kyklos 53(3):293–315

Mukherjee S (2019) Crime and Social Deprivation across States in India–insights from a Panel Data Discourse on Social Sustainability’. The Impact of Global Terrorism on Economic and Political Development. Emerald Publishing Limited, pp. 249–265

Mulok D, Kogid M, Lily J, Asid R (2017) The relationship between crime and economic growth in Malaysia: re-examine using bound test approach. Malays J Business Econ (MJBE) 3(1):15–26

Musavengane R, Siakwah P, Leonard L (2019) “Does the poor matter” in pro-poor driven sub-Saharan African cities? towards progressive and inclusive pro-poor tourism. Int J Tourism Cities 5(3):392–411

Neumayer E (2003) Good policy can lower violent crime: evidence from a cross-national panel of homicide rates, 1980–97. J Peace Res 40(6):619–640

OSAC (2017) Morocco 2017 crime & safety report: rabat. Overseas Security Advisory Council, Washington DC

Ouimet M (2012) A world of homicides the effect of economic development, income inequality, and excess infant mortality on the homicide rate for 165 countries in 2010. Homicide Stud 16(3):238–258

Pane H (2017) The Social Problems of National Poverty and Criminality in Indonesia. Int J Soc Sci Human Invention 4(8):3834–3836

Piatkowska SJ (2020) Poverty, inequality, and suicide rates: a Cross-National Assessment of the Durkheim Theory and the Stream Analogy of Lethal Violence. Soc Q. 19:1–26

Popa AM (2012) The impact of social factors on economic growth: empirical evidence for Romania and European Union countries. Rom J Fiscal Policy (RJFP) 3(2):1–16

Pridemore WA (2011) Poverty matters: a reassessment of the inequality–homicide relationship in cross-national studies. Br J Criminol 51(5):739–772

Ranis G, Stewart F, Ramirez A (2000) Economic growth and human development. World Dev 28(2):197–219

Saasa OS (2018) Poverty profile in sub-Saharan Africa: the challenge of addressing an elusive problem. Contested terrains and constructed categories. Routledge, Abingdon, pp 105–116

Sachsida A, de Mendonça MJC, Loureiro PR, Gutierrez MBS (2010) Inequality and criminality revisited: further evidence from Brazil. Empirical Econ 39(1):93–109

Saleh B (2011) Tunisia’s economic medicine, poverty and unemployment. https://www.pambazuka.org/governance/tunisias-economic-medicine-poverty-and-unemployment . Accessed 6 October 2018

Solinger DJ, Hu Y (2012) Welfare, wealth and poverty in urban China: the Dibao and its differential disbursement. China Q 211:741–764

South China Monitoring Report (2015). Big trouble in rural China: data reveals greater the wealth gap the higher the crime rate, and Hong Kong is feeling the effects. Law and crime section. https://www.scmp.com/news/hong-kong/law-crime/article/1876931/big-trouble-rural-china-data-reveals-greater-wealth-gap . Accessed 6 October 2018

Stamatel JP (2016) Democratic cultural values as predictors of cross-national homicide variation in Europe. Homicide Stud 20(3):239–256

Thamman B (2017) Causes of poverty in Uruguay. The Borgen project. https://borgenproject.org/causes-of-poverty-in-uruguay/ . Accessed 6 October 2018

Thorbecke E, Charumilind C (2002) Economic inequality and its socioeconomic impact. World Dev 30(9):1477–1495

Ulriksen MS (2012) Questioning the pro-poor agenda: examining the links between social protection and poverty. Dev Policy Rev 30(3):261–281

Vellala PS, Madala MK, Chattopadhyay U (2018) Econometric analysis of growth inclusiveness in India: evidence from cross-sectional data. Advances in finance & applied economics. Springer, Singapore, pp 19–38

Vergara R (2012) Crime prevention programs: evidence from CHILE. Dev Econ 50(1):1–24

Wang C (2017) Which dimension of income distribution drives crime? Evidence from the People’s Republic of China. Asian Development Bank, Working paper no: 704, Tokyo, Japan. https://www.adb.org/publications/which-dimension-income-distribution-drives-crime-prc . Accessed 6 October 2018

Wang H, Yao H, Kifer D, Graif C, Li Z (2017) Non-stationary model for crime rate inference using modern urban data. IEEE Trans Big Data 5(2):180–194

World Bank (2013). Brazil Fights Crime while Bringing Development to the Favelas. http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2013/03/21/brazil-crime-violence-favela . Accessed 6 October 2018

World Bank (2015) World Development Indicators. World Bank, Washington DC

Zaman K (2018) Crime-poverty nexus: an intellectual survey. Forensic Res Criminol Int J 6(5):327–329

Zaman K, Khilji BA (2014) A note on pro-poor social expenditures. Qual Quant 48(4):2121–2154

Zaman K, Usman B, Sheikh SM, Khan A, Kosnin ABM, Rosman ASB, Hishan SS (2019) Managing crime through quality education: a model of justice. Sci Justice 59(6):597–605

Zaman K, Al-Ghazali BM, Khan A, Rosman ASB, Sriyanto S, Hishan SS, Bakar ZA (2020) Pooled mean group estimation for growth, inequality, and poverty triangle: evidence from 124 Countries. J Poverty 24(3):222–240

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are thankful for King Saud university research project number (RSP-2019/87) for funding the study. The authors are indebted to the editor and reviewers for constructive comments that have helped to improve the quality of the manuscript.

Researchers Supporting Project number (RSP-2019/87), King Saud University, Riyadh, Saudi Arabia.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Department of Public Administration, Xi’an University of Architecture and Technology, Xi’an, China

Muhammad Khalid Anser

Higher Education Department Khyber Pakhtunkhwa, Government College of Management Sciences, Abbottabad, Pakistan

Zahid Yousaf

Department of Management, College of Business Administration, King Saud University, P.O. Box 71115, Riyadh, 11587, Saudi Arabia

Abdelmohsen A. Nassani & Saad M. Alotaibi

Department of Management, Aleppo University, Aleppo, Syria

Ahmad Kabbani

Department of Economics, University of Wah, Quaid Avenue, Wah Cantt, Pakistan

Khalid Zaman

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Contributions

The collection, processing and analysis of the data were carried out by the authors. All authors read and approved the final manuscript

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Khalid Zaman .

Ethics declarations

Competing interests.

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

See Table  7 , Figs.  2 , 3 , 4 and 5 .

figure 2

Source: World Bank ( 2015 )

Data trend at level.

figure 3

Source: World Bank ( 2015 ). ‘D’ indicates first difference

Data trend at first differenced

figure 4

Source: authors’ estimation. Note: ‘D’ shows first difference, while ‘LOG’ represents natural logarithm

Plots of IRF.

figure 5

VDA Estimates.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ .

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article.

Anser, M.K., Yousaf, Z., Nassani, A.A. et al. Dynamic linkages between poverty, inequality, crime, and social expenditures in a panel of 16 countries: two-step GMM estimates. Economic Structures 9 , 43 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-020-00220-6

Download citation

Received : 03 February 2020

Revised : 09 March 2020

Accepted : 29 May 2020

Published : 05 June 2020

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-020-00220-6

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Pro-poor growth
  • Income inequality
  • Quality education
  • Healthcare expenditures
  • System panel GMM

Jel classification

research paper on poverty and crime

Thank you for visiting nature.com. You are using a browser version with limited support for CSS. To obtain the best experience, we recommend you use a more up to date browser (or turn off compatibility mode in Internet Explorer). In the meantime, to ensure continued support, we are displaying the site without styles and JavaScript.

  • View all journals
  • Explore content
  • About the journal
  • Publish with us
  • Sign up for alerts
  • Open access
  • Published: 21 January 2021

Why do inequality and deprivation produce high crime and low trust?

  • Benoît De Courson 1 , 2 &
  • Daniel Nettle 2  

Scientific Reports volume  11 , Article number:  1937 ( 2021 ) Cite this article

66k Accesses

26 Citations

372 Altmetric

Metrics details

  • Human behaviour

Humans sometimes cooperate to mutual advantage, and sometimes exploit one another. In industrialised societies, the prevalence of exploitation, in the form of crime, is related to the distribution of economic resources: more unequal societies tend to have higher crime, as well as lower social trust. We created a model of cooperation and exploitation to explore why this should be. Distinctively, our model features a desperation threshold, a level of resources below which it is extremely damaging to fall. Agents do not belong to fixed types, but condition their behaviour on their current resource level and the behaviour in the population around them. We show that the optimal action for individuals who are close to the desperation threshold is to exploit others. This remains true even in the presence of severe and probable punishment for exploitation, since successful exploitation is the quickest route out of desperation, whereas being punished does not make already desperate states much worse. Simulated populations with a sufficiently unequal distribution of resources rapidly evolve an equilibrium of low trust and zero cooperation: desperate individuals try to exploit, and non-desperate individuals avoid interaction altogether. Making the distribution of resources more equal or increasing social mobility is generally effective in producing a high cooperation, high trust equilibrium; increasing punishment severity is not.

Similar content being viewed by others

research paper on poverty and crime

Inequality and cooperation in social networks

research paper on poverty and crime

Segregating socioeconomic classes leads to an unequal redistribution of wealth

research paper on poverty and crime

Social goods dilemmas in heterogeneous societies

Introduction.

Humans are often described as an unusually cooperative or ‘ultrasocial’ species 1 . The truth is more complex: humans from the same society can cooperate for mutual benefit; or they can simply co-exist; or they can actively exploit one another, as in, for example, crime. A theory of human sociality should ideally predict what mix of these alternatives will emerge under which circumstances. Comparing across industrialised societies, higher inequality—greater dispersion in the distribution of economic resources across individuals—is associated with higher crime and lower social trust 2 , 3 , 4 , 5 , 6 , 7 . These associations appear empirically robust, and meet epidemiological criteria for being considered causal 8 . However, the nature of the causal mechanisms is still debated. The effects of inequality are macroscopic phenomena, seen most clearly by comparing aggregates such as countries or states. It is their micro-foundations in individual psychology and behaviour that still require clarification.

There are, broadly, two classes of explanation for how inequality, a population-level phenomenon, could influence individual-level outcomes like crime or trust. The first class of explanation is compositional: in more unequal societies, the least fortunate individuals are absolutely worse off than in more equal societies of the same average wealth, exactly because the dispersion either side of the average is greater. Some individuals are also better off too, at the other end of the distribution, but if there is any non-linearity in the function relating individual resources to outcomes—if for example the poor becoming absolutely poorer has a larger effect on their propensity to offend than the rich becoming absolutely richer has on theirs—this can still change outcome prevalence in the population 9 , 10 , 11 . In line with compositional explanations, across US counties, the association between inequality and rate of property crime is fully mediated by the prevalence of poverty, which is higher in more unequal counties 2 . Moreover, changes in rates over time track changes in the economic prospects of people at the bottom end of the socioeconomic distribution 12 , 13 . The second class of explanation is psychosocial: individuals perceive the magnitude of social differentials in the society around them, and this affects their state of mind, increasing competitiveness, anxiety and self-serving individualism 8 , 14 . In this paper, we develop an explanatory model for why greater inequality should produce higher crime and lower social trust. Our model provides a bridge between compositional and psychosocial explanations. Its explanation for the inequality-crime association is compositional: individuals offend when their own absolute level of resources is desperately low, and the effect of increasing inequality is to make such desperation more prevalent. On the other hand, the model’s explanation for the inequality-trust association is more psychosocial: all individuals in high-inequality populations end up trusting less, regardless of their personal resource levels.

To provide a micro-foundation in individual behaviour for the macro-level effects of inequality on crime, we must start from explanations for why individuals commit crimes. Economic 15 , 16 and behavioural-ecological 17 approaches see offending as a strategic response to specific patterns of incentive. Economic models predict that offending should be more attractive when the payoffs from legitimate activity are low. This principle successfully explains variation in offending behaviour both within and between societies 12 , 16 . It can also explain the relationship between crime levels and inequality, in compositional manner, because unequal societies produce poorer legitimate opportunities for people at the lower end of the socioeconomic spectrum 2 . However, these models are generally taken to predict that making punishments for crime more severe should reduce the prevalence of offending, because harsher punishment should reduce the expected utility associated with the criminal option. Empirical evidence, though, does not clearly support the hypothesis that increasing punishment severity reduces offending 18 , 19 . There is more evidence for a deterrent effect of increased probability of punishment, though even this effect may be modest 18 , 19 .

Becker 15 pointed out that the puzzle of the weak deterrent effect of punishment severity would be solved if offenders were risk-preferring. The decision to offend is risky in that it has either a large positive payoff (if not caught) or a large negative one (if caught and punished). An individual who prefers risk might thus choose to offend even if the expected utility of offending is negative due to a possible severe punishment. Thus, the question becomes: why would some people—those who commit crime—prefer risk, when people are usually averse to it? To address this question, our model incorporates features of classic risk-sensitive foraging theory from behavioural ecology 20 (for a review in the context of human behaviour, see Ref. 21 ). Risk-sensitive foraging models incorporate a desperation threshold: a level of resources below which it is disastrous to fall, in the foraging case because of starvation. The models show that individuals in sufficient imminent danger of falling below this threshold ought to become risk-preferring. If a risky option is successful, it will allow them to leap back over the threshold; and if not, their prospects will be no more dire than they were anyway. Our model is novel in explicitly incorporating a desperation threshold into decisions about whether to cooperate (analogous in our model to participating in legitimate economic activity) or exploit others (analogous to committing an acquisitive crime).

The desperation threshold is the major theoretical innovation of our model. We justify its inclusion on multiple grounds. First, the ultimate currency in our model is fitness, a quantity with a natural biological interpretation that must necessarily be zero if the individual lacks the minimal resources to subsist and function socially. Thus, it is reasonable that expected fitness should be related to resource levels, but not linearly: there should be a point where, as resources deplete, expected fitness rapidly declines to zero. Our threshold assumption produces exactly this type of function (see Supplementary Sect.  2.1 , Supplementary Fig. S1 ). Second, in experimental games where gaining a payoff is subject to a threshold, people do switch to risk-proneness when in danger of falling below the threshold, as risk-sensitive foraging theory predicts 22 . Although this does not show that such thresholds are widespread or important in real life, it does show that people intuitively understand their implications when they are faced with them, and respond accordingly. Third, there are ethnographic descriptions of ‘disaster levels’, ‘crisis levels’, or ‘edges’ that affect the risk attitudes of people facing poverty 23 , 24 . For example, writing on Southeast Asia, Scott 23 describes the spectre of a “subsistence crisis level—perhaps a ‘danger zone’ rather than a ‘level’ would be more accurate…a threshold below which the qualitative deterioration in subsistence, security and status is massive and painful” (p. 17), as an ever-present factor in people’s decisions. Thus, including a desperation threshold is a simple but potentially powerful innovation into models of cooperation and exploitation, with potential to generate new insights.

In our model, agents repeatedly decide between three actions: foraging alone, foraging cooperatively, or exploiting a cooperative group. Foraging cooperatively is analogous to legitimate economic activity, and exploitation is analgous to acquisitive crime. Agents have variable levels of resources, and their behaviour is state-dependent. That is, rather than having a fixed strategy of always cooperating or always exploiting, each agent, at each interaction, selects a behaviour based on their current level of resources, the behaviour of others in the surrounding population, and background parameters such as the probability and severity of punishment, and the likelihood of resources improving through other means. Agents seek to maximize fitness. We assume that fitness is positively related to resource levels, but that there is a threshold, a critically low level of resources below which there is an immediate fitness penalty for falling. Our investigation of the model has two stages. We first compute the optimal action policy an individual should follow; that is, the optimal action to select for every possible combination of the situational variables. Second, we simulate populations of individuals all following the optimal action policies, to predict population-level outcomes for different initial resource distributions.

To explain the model in more detail, at each time point t in an indefinitely long sequence of time steps (where one time step is one economic interaction), agents have a current level of resources s. They can take one of three actions. Foraging alone costs x units of resources and is also guaranteed to return x. Thus, foraging alone is sufficient to maintain the agent but creates no increase in resources. It is also safe from exploitation, as we conceptualise it as involving minimal interaction with others. Alternatively, agents can team up with n-1 others to cooperate . As long as no other group member exploits, cooperation is mutually beneficial, costing x units but producing a payoff of \(\alpha x \left( {\alpha > 1} \right)\) to each group member. Finally, agents can exploit : join a cooperating group and try to selfishly divert the resources produced therein. If this exploitation is successful, they obtain a large reward β, but if they fail, they receive a punishment π. The probability of being punished is γ. The punishment is not administered by peers: we assume that there is a central punitive institution in place, and both the size and probability of punishment are exogenous. In our default case, the expected payoff for exploitation is zero (i.e. \(\left( {1 - \gamma } \right)\beta = \gamma \pi\) ), making exploitation no better than foraging alone on average, and worse than cooperating. However, the reward for a successful exploitation, β, is the largest payoff available to the agent in any single time step.

At every time step, each agent’s resource level is updated according to the outcomes of their action. In addition, resource levels change by a disturbance term controlled by a parameter r , such that the mean and variance of population resources are unchanged, but the temporal autocorrelation of agents’ resource levels is only 1 −  r . If r is high, individuals whose current resources are low can expect they will be higher in the future and vice versa, because of regression to the mean. If \(r = 0\) , resources will never change other than by the agent’s actions. We consider r a measure of social mobility due to causes other than choice of actions.

In the first stage, we use stochastic dynamic programming 25 , 26 to compute the optimal action policy. Fitness is a positive linear function of expected resource level s in the future. However, in computing the fitness payoffs of each action, we also penalize, by a fixed amount, any action that leaves the agent below a desperation threshold in the next time step (arbitrarily, we set this threshold at s  = 0). The optimal action policy identifies which one of the three actions is favoured for every possible combination of the factors that impinge on the agent. These include both their own current resource state s , and features of their social world, such as the severity of punishment π, the probability of punishment γ, and the level of social mobility r. A critical variable that enters into the computation of the optimal action is the probability that any cooperating group in the population will contain someone who exploits. We denote this probability p . We can think of 1 −  p as an index of the trustworthiness of the surrounding population. Computing the optimal policy effectively allows us to ask: under what circumstances should an individual forage alone, cooperate, or exploit?

In the second stage, we simulate populations of agents all following the optimal policies computed in the first stage. We can vary the starting distributions of resources (their mean and dispersion), as well as other parameters such as social mobility and the probability and severity of punishment. During the simulation stage, each agent forms an estimate of 1 −  p , the trustworthiness of others, through observing the behaviour of a randomly-selected subset of other individuals. We refer to these estimates as the agents’ social trust, since social trust is defined as the generalized expectation that others will behave well 27 . Social trust updates at the end of each time step. Agents’ social trust values are unbiased estimates of the current trustworthiness of the surrounding population, but they are not precise, because they are based on only a finite sample of other population members. The simulation stage, allows us to ask: what are the predicted temporal dynamics of behaviour, and of social trust, in populations with different starting distributions of resources, different levels of social mobility, and different punishments for exploitation?

Each of the three actions is optimal in a different region of the space formed by current resources s and the trustworthiness of others 1 −  p (Fig.  1 a). Below a critical value of s , agents should always exploit, regardless of trustworthiness . In the default case, this critical value is in the vicinity of the desperation threshold, though it can be lower or higher depending on the value of other parameters. With our default values, exploitation will not, on average, make the agent’s resource state any better in subsequent time steps. However, there is a large advantage to getting above the threshold in the next time step, and there is a region of the resource continuum where exploitation is the only action that can achieve this in one go (intuitively, it is the quickest way to ‘get one’s head above water’). Where s is above the critical value, cooperation is optimal as long as the trustworthiness of the surrounding population is sufficiently high. However, if trustworthiness is too low, the likelihood of getting exploited makes cooperation worse than foraging alone. The shape of the frontier between cooperation and foraging alone is complex when resources are close to the desperation threshold. This is because cooperation and foraging alone also differ in riskiness; foraging alone is risk-free, but cooperation carries a risk of being exploited that depends on trustworthiness. Just above the exploitation zone, there is a small region where cooperation is favoured even at low trustworthiness, since one successful cooperation would be enough to hurdle back over the threshold, but foraging alone would not. Just above this is a zone where foraging alone is favoured even at high trustworthiness; here the agent will be above the threshold in the next time period unless they are a victim of exploitation, which makes them averse to taking the risk of cooperating.

figure 1

Optimal actions as a function of the individual’s current resources s and the trustworthiness of the surrounding population, 1 −  p . ( A ) All parameters at their default values. This includes: α = 1.2, r = 0.1, π = 10, and γ = 1/3 (see Table 1 for a full list). ( B ) Effect of altering the efficiency of cooperation α to be either lower (1.05) or higher (1.30) than ( A ). Other parameter values are as for ( A ). ( C ) Effects of varying social mobility, to be either high (r = 0.8), or complete (r = 1.0; i.e. resource levels in this time period have no continuity at all into the next). Other parameter values are as for ( A ). ( D ) Effect of increasing the severity of punishment for exploiters to π = 15 and π = 20. Other parameter values are as for ( A ). ( E ). Effects of altering the probability of punishment for exploiters to γ = 2/3 and γ = 9/10. Other parameter values are as for ( A ).

We explored the sensitivity of the optimal policy to changes in parameter values. Increasing the profitability of cooperation (α) decreases the level of trustworthiness that is required for cooperation to be worthwhile (Fig.  1 B; analytically, the cooperation/foraging alone frontier for \(s \gg 0\) is at \(\left( {1 - p} \right) = 1/\alpha\) ; see Supplementary Sect.  2.2 ). A very high level of social mobility r moves the critical value for exploitation far to the left (i.e. individuals have to be in an even more dire state before they start to exploit; Fig.  1 C). This is because with high social mobility, badly-off individuals can expect that their level of resources will regress towards the mean over time anyway, lessening the need for risky action when faced with a small immediate shortfall.

The optimality of exploitation below the critical level of resources is generally insensitive to increasing the severity of punishment, π (Fig.  1 D), even where the expected value of exploitation is thereby rendered negative. This is because a desperate agent will be below the threshold in the next time step anyway if they forage alone, cooperate, or receive a punishment of any size. They are so badly off that it is relatively unimportant how much worse things get, but important to take any small chance of ‘jumping over’ the threshold. The exploitation boundary is slightly more sensitive to the probability of punishment, γ, though even this sensitivity is modest (Fig.  1 E). When γ is very high, it is optimal for agents very close to the boundary of desperation to take a gamble on cooperating, even where trustworthiness is rather low. Although this is risky, it offers a better chance of getting back above the threshold than exploitation that is almost bound to fail. Nonetheless, it is striking that even where exploitation is almost bound to fail and attracts a heavy penalty, it is still the best option for an individual whose current resource level is desperately low.

We also explored the effect of setting either the probability γ or the severity π of punishment so low that the expected payoff from exploitation is positive. This produces a pattern where exploitation is optimal if an agent’s resources are either desperately low, or comfortably high (see Supplementary Fig. S2 ). Only in the middle—currently above the threshold, but not by far enough that a punishment would not pull them down below it–should agents cooperate or forage alone.

We simulated populations of N  = 500 individuals each following the optimal policy, with the distribution of initial resources s drawn from a distribution with mean μ and standard deviation σ. Populations fall into one of two absorbing equilibria. In the first, the poverty trap (Fig.  2 A), there is no cooperation after the first few time periods. Instead, there is a balance of attempted exploitation and foraging alone, with the proportions of these determined by the initial resource distribution and the values of π and γ. The way this equilibrium develops is as follows: there is a sufficiently high frequency of exploitation in the first round (about 10% of the population or more is required) that subsequent social trust estimates are mostly very low. With trust low, those with the higher resource levels switch to foraging alone, whilst those whose resources are desperately low continue to try to exploit. Since foraging alone produces no surplus, the population mean resources never increases, and both exploiters and lone foragers are stuck where they were.

figure 2

The two equilibria in simulated populations. ( A ) The poverty trap. There is sufficient exploitation in the first time step ( A1 ) that social trust is low ( A2 ). Consequently, potential cooperators switch to lone foraging, resources never increase ( A3 ), and a subgroup of the population is left below the threshold seeking to exploit. Simulation initialised with μ = 5.5, σ = 4 and all other parameters at their default values. ( B ) The virtuous circle. Exploitation is sufficiently rare from the outset ( B1 ) that trust is high ( B2 ) and individuals switch from lone foraging to cooperation. This drives an increase in resources, eventually lifting almost all individuals above the threshold. Simulation initialised with μ = 5.5, σ = 3 and all other parameters at their default values.

In the second equilibrium, the virtuous circle (Fig.  2 B), the frequency of exploitation is lower at the outset. Individuals whose resources are high form high assessments of social trust, and hence choose cooperation over foraging alone. Since cooperation creates a surplus, the mean level of resources in the population increases. This benefits the few exploiters, both through the upward drift of social mobility, and because they sometimes exploit successfully. This resolves the problem of exploitation, since in so doing they move above the critical value to the point where it is no longer in their interests to exploit, and since they are in such a high-trust population, they then start to cooperate. Thus, over time, trust becomes universally high, resources grow, and cooperation becomes almost universal.

Each of the two equilibria has a basin of attraction in the space of initial population characteristics. The poverty trap is reached if the fraction of individuals whose resource levels fall below the level that triggers exploitation is sufficiently large at any point. With the desperation threshold at s = 0, his fraction is affected by both the mean resources μ, and inequality σ. For a given μ, increasing σ (i.e. greater inequality) makes it more likely that the poverty trap will result, because, by broadening the resource distribution, the tail that protrudes into the desperation zone is necessarily made larger.

The boundaries of the basin of attraction of the poverty trap are also affected by severity of punishment, probability of punishment, and the level of social mobility (Fig.  3 ). If the severity of punishment π is close to zero, there is no disincentive to exploit, and the poverty trap always results. As long as a minimum size of punishment is met, further increases in punishment severity have no benefit in preventing the poverty trap (Fig.  3 A). Indeed, there are circumstances where more severe punishment can make things worse. When the population has a degree of initial inequality that puts it close to the boundary between the two equilibria, very severe punishment (π = 20 or π = 25) pushes it into the poverty trap. This is because any individual that once tries exploitation because they are close to threshold (and is unsuccessful) is pushed so far down in resources by the punishment that they must then continue to exploit forever. Increasing the probability of punishment γ does not have this negative effect (Fig.  3 B). Instead, a very high probability of punishment can forestall the poverty trap at levels of inequality where it would otherwise occur, because it causes some of the worst-off individuals to try cooperating instead, as shown in Fig.  1 E. Finally, very high levels of social mobility r can rescue populations from the poverty trap even at high levels of inequality (Fig.  3 C). This is because of its dramatic effect on the critical value at which individuals start to exploit, as shown in Fig.  1 C.

figure 3

Equilibrium population states by starting parameters. ( A ) Varying the initial inequality in resources σ and the severity of punishment π, whilst holding constant the probability of punishment γ at 1/3 and social mobility r at 0.1. ( B ) Varying the initial inequality in resources σ and the probability of punishment γ whilst holding the severity of punishment constant at π = 10 and social mobility r at 0.1. ( C ) Varying the initial inequality in resources σ and the level of social mobility r whilst holding constant the probability of punishment γ at 1/3 and the severity of punishment π at 10.

Though the equilibria are self-perpetuating without exogenous forces, the system is highly responsive to shocks. For example, exogenously changing the level of inequality in the population (via imposing a reduction in σ after 16 time steps) produces a phase transition from the poverty trap to the virtuous circle (Supplementary Fig. S3 ). This change is not instantaneous. First, a few individuals cross the threshold and change from exploitation to foraging alone; this produces a consequent change in social trust; which then leads to a mass switch to cooperation, and growth in mean wealth.

Results so far are all based on cooperation occurring in groups of size n  = 5. Reducing n enlarges the basin of attraction of the virtuous circle (Supplementary Sect.  2.5 , Supplementary Fig. S4 ). This is because, for any given population prevalence of exploitation, there is more likely to be at least one exploiter in a group of five than a group of three. Reducing the interaction group size changes the trustworthiness boundary between the region where it is optimal to cooperate and the region where it is better to forage alone. Thus, there are parameter values in our model where populations would succumb to the poverty trap by attempting to mount large cooperation groups, but avoid it by restricting cooperation groups to a smaller size.

In our model, exploiting others can be an individual’s optimal strategy under certain circumstances, namely when their resource levels are very low, and cannot be expected to spontaneously improve. We extend previous models by showing that it can be optimal to exploit even when the punishment for doing so and being caught is large enough to make the expected utility of exploitation negative. Two conditions combine to make this the case. First, exploitation produces a large variance in payoffs: it is costly to exploit and be caught, but there is a chance of securing a large positive payoff. Second, there is a threshold of desperation below which it is extremely costly to fall. It is precisely when at risk of falling below this threshold that exploitation becomes worthwhile: if it succeeds, one hurdles the threshold, and if it fails, one is scarcely worse off than one would have been anyway. In effect, due to the threshold, there is a point where agents have little left to lose, and this makes them risk-preferring. Thus, our model results connect classic economic models of crime 15 , 16 to risk-sensitive foraging theory from behavioural ecology 20 . In the process, it provides a simple answer to the question that has puzzled a number of authors 18 , 19 : why aren’t increases in the severity of punishments as deterrent as simple expected utility considerations imply they ought to be? Our model suggests that, beyond a minimum required level of punishment, not only might increasing severity be ineffective at reducing exploitation. It could under some circumstances make exploitation worse, by pushing punishees into such a low resource state that they have no reasonable option but to continue exploiting. Our findings also have implications for the literature on the evolution of cooperation. This has shown that punishment can be an effective mechanism for stabilising cooperation 28 , 29 , but have not considered that the deterrent effects of punishment may be different for different individuals, due to variation in their states. Our findings could be relevant to understanding why some level of exploitation persists in practice even when punishment is deterrent overall.

Within criminology, our prediction of risky exploitative behaviour when in danger of falling below a threshold of desperation is reminiscent of Merton’s strain theory of deviance 30 , 31 . Under this theory, deviance results when individuals have a goal (remaining constantly above the threshold of participation in society), but the available legitimate means are insufficient to get them there (neither foraging alone nor cooperation has a large enough one-time payoff). They thus turn to risky alternatives, despite the drawbacks of these (see also Ref. 32 for similar arguments). This explanation is not reducible to desperation making individuals discount the future more steeply, which is often invoked as an explanation for criminality 33 . Agents in our model do not face choices between smaller-sooner and larger-later rewards; the payoff for exploitation is immediate, whether successful or unsuccessful. Also note the philosophical differences between our approach and ‘self-control’ styles of explanation 34 . Those approaches see offending as deficient decision-making: it would be in people’s interests not to offend, but some can’t manage it (see Ref. 35 for a critical review). Like economic 15 , 16 and behavioural-ecological 17 theories of crime more generally, ours assumes instead that there are certain situations or states where offending is the best of a bad set of available options.

As well as a large class of circumstances where only individuals in a poor resource state will choose to exploit, we also identify some—where the expected payoff for exploitation is positive—where individuals with both very low and very high resources exploit, whilst those in the middle avoid doing so. Such cases have been anticipated in theories of human risk-sensitivity 21 . These distinguish risk-preference through need (e.g. to get back above the threshold immediately) from risk-preference through ability (e.g. to absorb a punishment with no ill effects), predicting that both can occur under some circumstances 32 . This dual form of risk-taking is best analogised to a situation where punishments take the form of fines: those who are desperate have to run the risk of incurring them, even though they can ill afford it; whilst those who are extremely well off can simply afford to pay them if caught. When we simulate populations of agents all following the optimal strategies identified by the model, population-level characteristics (inequality of resources, level of social mobility) affect the prevalence of exploitation and the level of trust. Specifically, holding constant the average level of resources, greater inequality makes frequent exploitation and low trust a more likely outcome. Thus, we capture the widely-observed associations between inequality, trust and crime levels that were our starting point 2 , 3 , 4 , 5 , 6 . Note that our explanation for the inequality-crime nexus is basically compositional rather than psychosocial. Decisions to offend are based primarily on agents’ own levels of resources; these are just more likely to be desperately low in more unequal populations. Turning these simulation findings into empirical predictions, we would expect the association between inequality and crime rates to be driven by more unequal societies producing worse prospects for people at the bottom end of the resources distribution, who would be the ones who turn to property crime. Inequality effects at the aggregate level should be largely mediated by individual-level poverty. There is evidence compatible with these claims for property crime 2 , 12 , 13 . This is the type of crime most similar to our modelled situation. Non-acquisitive crimes of violence, though related to inequality, do not appear so strongly mediated by individual-level poverty, and may thus require different but related explanations 2 , 36 .

However, the other major result of our population simulations—that more unequal populations are more likely to produce low trust—is not compositional. In our unequal simulated populations, every agent has low trust, not just the ones at the bottom of the resource distribution. This is compatible with empirical evidence: the association between inequality and social trust survives controlling for individual poverty 6 . Thus, our model generates a genuinely ecological effect of inequality on social relationships that fits the available evidence and links it to the psychosocial tradition of explanation 37 . Indeed, the model suggests a reason why psychosocial effects should arise. For agents above the threshold, the optimal decision between cooperation and foraging alone depends on inferences about whether anyone else in the population will exploit. To know that, you have to attend to the behaviour of everyone else, not just your own state. Thus, the model naturally generates a reason for agents to be sensitive to the distribution of others’ states in the population (or at the very least their behaviour), and to condition their social engagement with others on it.

In as much as our model provides a compositional explanation for the inequality-crime relationship, it might seem to imply that high levels of inequality would not lead to high crime as long as the mean wealth of the population was sufficiently high. This is because, with high mean wealth, even those in the bottom tail of the distribution would have sufficient levels of resources to be above the threshold of desperation. However, this implication would only follow if the location of the desperation threshold is considered exogenous and fixed. If, instead, the location of the desperation threshold moves upwards with mean wealth of the population, then more inequality will always produce more acquisitive crime, regardless of the mean level of population wealth. Assuming that the threshold moves in this way is a reasonable move: definitions of poverty for developed countries are expressed in terms of the resources required to live a life seen as acceptable or normal within that society, not an absolute dollar value (see Ref. 36 , pp. 64–6). Moreover, there is clear evidence that people compare themselves to relevant others in assessing the adequacy of their resources 38 . Thus, we would expect inequality to remain important for crime regardless of overall economic growth.

In addition to the results concerning inequality, we found that social mobility should, other things being equal, reduce the prevalence of exploitation, although social mobility has to be very high for the effect to be substantial. The pattern can again be interpreted as consistent with Merton’s strain theory of deviance 31 : very high levels of social mobility provide legitimate routes for those whose state is poor to improve it, thus reducing the zone where deviance is required. Economists have noted that those places within the USA with higher levels of intergenerational social mobility also have lower crime rates 39 , 40 . Their account of the causality in this association is the reverse of ours: the presence of crime, particularly violent crime, inhibits upward mobility 39 . However, it is possible that social mobility and crime are mutually causative.

Like any model, ours simplifies social situations to very bare elements. Interaction groups are drawn randomly at every time step from the whole population. Thus, there are no ongoing personal relationships, no reputation, no social networks, no kinship, no segregation or assortment of sub-groups. The model best captures social groups with frequent new interactions between strangers, which is appropriate since the phenomena under investigated are documented for commercial and industrial societies. A problem in mapping our findings onto empirical reality is that our population simulations generate two discrete equilibria: zero trust, economic stagnation and zero cooperation, or almost perfect trust, unlimited economic growth and zero exploitation. Although we show that the distribution of resources determines which equilibrium is reached, our model as presented here does generate the continuous relationships between inequality, crime, and trust (or indeed inequality and economic growth 41 ) that have been observed in reality. Even the most unequal real society features some social cooperation, and even the most equal features some property crime; the effects of inequality are graded. We make two points to try to bridge the disconnect between the black and white world of the simulations and the shades of grey seen in reality. First, our model does predict a continuous relationship between the level of inequality and the maximum size of cooperating groups. A highly unequal population, containing many individuals with an incentive to exploit, might only be able to sustain collective actions at the level of a few individuals, whereas a more equal population where almost no-one has an incentive to exploit could sustain far larger ones. Second, we appeal to all the richness of real social processes that our model excludes. In unequal countries, although social trust is relatively low, people can draw more heavily on their established social networks and reputational information; more homogenous sub-groups can segregate themselves; people can use defensive security measures, to keep cooperative relationships ongoing and protected; and so forth. Investment in these kinds of measures may vary proportionately with inequality and trust, thus maintaining outcomes intermediate between the stark equilibria of our simulations. Our key findings also depend entirely on accepting the notion that there is a threshold of desperation, a substantial non-linearity in the value of having resources. As we outlined in the Introduction, we believe there are good grounds for exploring the implications of such an assumption. However, that is very different from claiming that the widespread existence of such thresholds has been demonstrated. We hope our findings might generate empirical investigation into both the objective reality and psychological appraisal of such thresholds for people in poverty.

Limitations and simplifications duly noted, our model does have some clear implications. Large population-scale reductions in crime and exploitation should not be expected to follow from increasing the severity of punishments, and these could conceivably be counterproductive. Addressing basic distributional issues that leave large numbers of people in desperate circumstances and without legitimate means to improve them will have a much greater effect. Natural-experimental evidence supports this. The Eastern Cherokee, a Native American group with a high rate of poverty, distributed casino royalties through an unconditional income scheme. Rates of minor offending amongst young people in recipient households decline markedly, with no changes to the judicial regime 42 . Improving the distribution of resources would also be expected to increase social trust, and with it, the quality of human relationships; and this, for everyone, not just those in desperate circumstances.

The model was written in Python and implemented via a Jupyter notebook. For a fuller description of the model, see Supplementary Sect.  1 and Supplementary Table S1 .

Computing optimal policies

We used a stochastic dynamic programming algorithm 25 , 26 . Agents choose among a set of possible actions, defined by (probabilistic) consequences for the agent’s level of resources s . We seek, for every possible value of s and of p the agent might face, and given the values of other parameters, the action that maximises expected fitness. Maximization is achieved through backward induction: we begin with a ‘last time step’ ( T ) where terminal fitness is defined, as an increasing linear function of resource level s . Then in the period T  − 1 we compute for each combination of state variables and action the expected fitness at T , and thus choose for the optimal action for every combination of states. This allows us define expected fitness for every value of the state variables at T  − 1, repeat the maximization for time step T  − 2, and so on iteratively. The desperation threshold is implemented as a fixed fitness penalty ω that is applied whenever the individual’s resources are below the threshold level s  = 0. As the calculation moves backwards away from T , the resulting mapping of state variables to optimal actions converges to a long term optimal policy.

Actions and payoffs

Agents choose among three actions:

Cooperate The agent invests x units of resource and is rewarded α · x with probability 1 −  p ( p is the probability of cooperation being exploited, and 1 −  p is therefore the trustworthiness of the surrounding population), and 0 with probability p . The net payoff is therefore x · ( α  − 1) if there is no exploitation and −  x if there is. We assume that α  > 1 (by default α  = 1 . 2), which means that cooperation is more efficient than foraging alone. For the computation of optimal policies, we treat p as an exogenous variable. In the population simulations, it becomes endogenous.

Exploit An agent joins a cooperating group, but does not invest x, and instead tries to steal their partners’ investments, leading to a reward of β if the exploitation succeeds and a cost π if it fails. The probability of exploitation failing (i.e. being punished) is γ .

Forage alone The agent forages alone, investing x units of resource, receiving x in return, and suffering no risk of exploitation.

Payoffs are also affected by a random perturbation, so the above-mentioned payoffs are just the expected values. A simple form such as the addition of \(\varepsilon \sim N\left( {0, \sigma^{2} } \right)\) would be unsuitable when used in population simulations. As the variance of independent random variables is additive, it would lead to an ever increasing dispersion of resource levels in the population. To avoid this issue, we adopted a perturbation in the form of a first-order autoregressive process that does not change either the mean or the variance of resources in the population 43 :

Here, µ is the current mean resources in the population and σ 2 the population variance. The term \(\left( {1 - r} \right) \in \left[ {0, 1} \right]\) represents the desired correlation between an agent’s current and subsequent resources, which leads to us describing r as the ‘social mobility’ of the population. The perturbation can be seen as a ‘shuffle’. Each agent’s resource level is attracted to µ with a strength depending on r , but this regression to the mean is exactly offset at the population level by the variance added by the perturbation, so that the overall distribution of resources is roughly unchanged. If r  = 1, current resources are not informative about future resources.

The dynamic programming equation

Let I be the set of actions ( cooperate , exploit and alone ), which we shorten as I  = { C,H,A }. For i   ∈   I , we denote as \(\phi_{t}^{i} \left( {s, .} \right)\) the probability density of resources in in time step t if, in time step t  − 1, the resource level is s and the chosen action i . The expressions of these functions were obtained through the law of total probability, conditioning on the possible outcomes of the actions (e.g. success or failure of exploitation and cooperation), and with the Gaussian density of the random variable.

We can now write the dynamic programming equation, which gives the backward recurrence relation to compute the payoff values (and the decisions) at the period t from the ones at the period t  + 1.

Here, \(E_{i}\) is the conditional expectation if action i is played. The optimal action for the time step t is \({\text{argmax}}_{i \in I} E_{i} (f_{t} )\) . The resource variable s was bounded in the interval [− 50, 50], and discretized with 1001 steps of size 0 . 1.

For any given set of parameters (summarised in Table 1 ), we can therefore compute the optimal decision rule. Note that we can distinguish two types of parameters:

‘Structural parameters’, i.e. those defining the ‘rules’ of the game (the payoffs for the actions and the level of social mobility r , for example). In the subsequent simulation phase, these parameters will be fixed for any run of the simulations.

‘Input parameters’, such as p and s . In the simulation phase, these will evolve endogenously.

Optimal policies rapidly stabilize as the computation moves away from T . We report optimal actions at t  = 1 as the globally optimal actions.

Population simulations

We begin each simulation by initializing a population of N  = 500 individuals, whose resource levels are randomly drawn from a Gaussian distribution with a given mean µ and variance σ 2 . At each time step, interaction groups of n  = 5 individuals are formed at random, and re-formed at each time step to avoid effects of assortment. There is no spatial structure in the populations. Each individual always follows the optimal policy for its resources s and its estimate of p (see below). Varying N has no effect as long as N  >  n and 500 is simply chosen for computational convenience.

To deal with the case where several members of the same interaction group choose to exploit, we choose one at random that exploits, and the others are deemed to forage alone (in effect, there is nothing left for them to take). Also, when there is no cooperator in the group, all exploiters are deemed to forage alone.

Rather than providing each individual with perfect knowledge of the trustworthiness of the rest of the population 1 −  p , we allow individuals to form an estimate (their social trust ) from their experience. Social trust is derived in the following way. Each agent observes the decision of a sample of K individuals in the population, counts the number k of exploiters and infers an (unbiased) estimate of the prevalence of exploiters in the population: \(k^{\prime} = \frac{k}{K}N\) (rounded). The size of the sample can be varied to alter the precision with which agents can estimate trustworthiness. Unless otherwise stated we used K  = 50. Since p is the probability that there will be at least one exploiter in an interaction group, it is one minus the probability that there will be zero exploiters. Each agent computes this from their k’ by combinatorics.

An intentional consequence of social trust being estimated through sampling is that there is some population heterogeneity in social trust, and therefore in decisions about which action to take, even for agents with the same resources s . Note also that agents infer trustworthiness not from observing the particular individuals in their current interaction group, but rather, from a cross-section of the entire population. Thus, the estimate is genuinely social trust (the perception that people in society generally do or do not behave well).

Code availability

The Jupyter notebook for running the model is available at: https://github.com/regicid/Deprivation-antisociality . This repository also contains R code and datafiles used to make the figures in the paper.

Tomasello, M. The ultra-social animal. Eur. J. Soc. Psychol. 44 , 187–194 (2014).

Article   Google Scholar  

Kelly, M. Inequality and crime. Rev. Econ. Stat. 82 , 530–569 (2000).

Rufrancos, H. & Power, M. Income inequality and crime: A review and explanation of the time-series evidence. Sociol. Criminol. 1 , 1–9 (2013).

Google Scholar  

Krohn, M. D. Inequality, unemployment and crime: A cross-national analysis. Sociol. Q. 17 , 303–313 (1976).

Barone, G. & Mocetti, S. Inequality and trust: New evidence from panel data. Econ. Inq. 54 , 794–809 (2016).

Kennedy, B. P., Kawachi, I., Prothrow-Stith, D., Lochner, K. & Gupta, V. Social capital, income inequality, and firearm violent crime. Soc. Sci. Med. 47 , 7–17 (1998).

Article   CAS   Google Scholar  

Oishi, S., Kesebir, S. & Diener, E. Income inequality and happiness. Psychol. Sci. 22 , 1095–1100 (2011).

Pickett, K. E. & Wilkinson, R. G. Income inequality and health: A causal review. Soc. Sci. Med. 128 , 316–326 (2015).

Ecob, R. & Davey Smith, G. Income and health: What is the nature of the relationship?. Soc. Sci. Med. 48 , 693–705 (1999).

Nettle, D. Why inequality is bad. In Hanging on to the Edges: Essays on Science, Society and the Academic Lifeg 111–128 (OpenBook Publishers, 2018).

Pridemore, W. A. A methodological addition to the cross-national empirical literature on social structure and homicide: A first test of the poverty-homicide thesis. Criminology 46 , 133–154 (2008).

Machin, S. & Meghir, C. Crime and economic incentives. J. Hum. Resour. 39 , 958–979 (2004).

Raphael, S. & Winter-Ebner, R. Identifying the effect of unemployment on crime. J. Law Econ. 44 , 259–283 (2001).

Wilkinson, R. G. & Pickett, K. E. The Spirit Level: Why Equal Societies Almost Always Do Better . (Allen Lane, 2009).

Becker, G. S. Crime and punishment: An economic approach. J. Polit. Econ. 76 , 169–217 (1968).

Ehrlich, I. Participation in illegitimate activities: A theoretical and empirical investigation. J. Polit. Econ. 81 , 521–565 (1973).

Cohen, L. E. & Machalek, R. A general theory of expropriative crime: An evolutionary ecological approach. Am. J. Sociol. 94 , 465–501 (1988).

Dölling, D., Entorf, H., Hermann, D. & Rupp, T. Is deterrence effective? Results of a meta-analysis of punishment. Eur. J. Crim. Policy Res. 15 , 201–224 (2009).

Nagin, D. S. Deterrence: A review of the evidence by a criminologist for economists. Annu. Rev. Econ. 5 , 83–105 (2013).

Stephens, D. W. The logic of risk-sensitive foraging preferences. Anim. Behav. 29 , 628–629 (1981).

Mishra, S., Barclay, P. & Sparks, A. The relative state model: Integrating need-based and ability-based pathways to risk-taking. Personal. Soc. Psychol. Rev. 21 , 176–198 (2017).

Mishra, S. & Lalumière, M. L. You can’t always get what you want: The motivational effect of need on risk-sensitive decision-making. J. Exp. Soc. Psychol. 46 , 605–611 (2010).

Scott, J. C. The Moral Economy of the Peasant: Rebellion and Subsistence in Southeast Asia . (Yale University Press, London, 1976).

Nettle, D. Tyneside Neighbourhoods: Deprivation, Social Life and Social Behaviour in One British City . (OpenBook Publishers, 2015).

Houston, A. I. & McNamara, J. M. Models of Adaptive Behaviour: An Approach Based on State . (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1999).

Mangel, M. & Clark, C. W. Dynamic Modeling in Behavioral Ecology . (Princeton University Press, Princeton, 1988).

Verducci, S. & Schröer, A. Social Trust. In International Encyclopedia of Civil Society (eds. Anheier, H. K. & Toepler, S.) 1453–1458 (Springer US, 2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-387-93996-4_68 .

Boyd, R. & Richerson, P. J. Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups. Ethol. Sociobiol. 13 , 171–195 (1992).

García, J. & Traulsen, A. Evolution of coordinated punishment to enforce cooperation from an unbiased strategy space. J. R. Soc. Interface 16 , 20190127 (2019).

Baumer, E. P. & Gustafson, R. Social organization and instrumental crime: Assessing the empirical validity of classic and contemporary anomie theories. Criminology 45 , 617–663 (2007).

Merton, R. K. Social structure and anomie. Am. Sociol. Rev. 3 , 672–682 (1938).

Barclay, P., Mishra, S. & Sparks, A. M. State-dependent risk-taking. Proc. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 285 , 20180180 (2018).

Lee, C. A., Derefinko, K. J., Milich, R., Lynam, D. R. & DeWall, C. N. Longitudinal and reciprocal relations between delay discounting and crime. Pers. Individ. Dif. 111 , 193–198 (2017).

Gottfredson, M. R. & Hirshi, T. A General Theory of Crime . (Stanford University Press, Stanford, 1990).

Burt, C. H. Self-control and crime: Beyond Gottfredson & Hirschi’s theory. Annu. Rev. Criminol. 3 , 43–73 (2020).

Daly, M. Killing the Competition: Economic Inequality and Homicide . (Transaction, 2016).

Wilkinson, R. G. & Pickett, K. E. The enemy between us: The psychological and social costs of inequality. Eur. J. Soc. Psychol. 47 , 11–24 (2017).

Payne, B. K., Brown-Iannuzzi, J. L. & Hannay, J. W. Economic inequality increases risk taking. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U. S. A. 114 , 4643–4648 (2017).

Sharkey, P. & Torrats-Espinosa, G. The effect of violent crime on economic mobility. J. Urban Econ. 102 , 22–33 (2017).

Chetty, R., Hendren, N., Kline, P. & Saez, E. Where is the land of opportunity? The geography of intergenerational mobility in the United States. Q. J. Econ. 129 , 1553–1623 (2014).

Alesina, A. & Rodrik, D. Distributive politics and economic growth. Q. J. Econ. 109 , 465–490 (1994).

Akee, K. Q. R., Copeland, W., Keeler, G., Angold, A. & Costello, E. J. Parents’ incomes and childrens’ outcomes: A quasi-experiment. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 2 , 86–115 (2010).

Bateson, M. & Nettle, D. The telomere lengthening conundrum—it could be biology. Aging Cell 16 , 312–319 (2017).

Download references

Acknowledgements

This project has received funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme (Grant agreement No AdG 666669, COMSTAR). The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish or preparation of the manuscript. The authors thank Melissa Bateson, Juliette Dronne, Ulysse Klatzmann, Daniel Krupp, Kate Pickett, and Rebecca Saxe for their input.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Institut Jean Nicod, Département d’études cognitives, ENS, EHESS, PSL Research University, CNRS, Paris, France

Benoît De Courson

Population Health Sciences Institute, Newcastle University, Newcastle, UK

Benoît De Courson & Daniel Nettle

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Contributions

The project was conceived jointly by B.C. and D.N. The model was developed and programmed by B.C. with feedback from D.N. B.C. wrote the first draft of the paper. The two authors revised and refined it collaboratively.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Daniel Nettle .

Ethics declarations

Competing interests.

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Supplementary information., rights and permissions.

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ .

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article.

De Courson, B., Nettle, D. Why do inequality and deprivation produce high crime and low trust?. Sci Rep 11 , 1937 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-020-80897-8

Download citation

Received : 02 November 2020

Accepted : 23 December 2020

Published : 21 January 2021

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-020-80897-8

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

This article is cited by

Leveraging social cognition to promote effective climate change mitigation.

  • Mélusine Boon-Falleur
  • Aurore Grandin
  • Coralie Chevallier

Nature Climate Change (2022)

By submitting a comment you agree to abide by our Terms and Community Guidelines . If you find something abusive or that does not comply with our terms or guidelines please flag it as inappropriate.

Quick links

  • Explore articles by subject
  • Guide to authors
  • Editorial policies

Sign up for the Nature Briefing newsletter — what matters in science, free to your inbox daily.

research paper on poverty and crime

U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

The .gov means it’s official. Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

The site is secure. The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

  • Publications
  • Account settings
  • My Bibliography
  • Collections
  • Citation manager

Save citation to file

Email citation, add to collections.

  • Create a new collection
  • Add to an existing collection

Add to My Bibliography

Your saved search, create a file for external citation management software, your rss feed.

  • Search in PubMed
  • Search in NLM Catalog
  • Add to Search

Income inequality, poverty and crime across nations

Affiliation.

  • 1 Department of Sociology, University of Western Ontario.
  • PMID: 25251139
  • DOI: 10.1111/1468-4446.12083

We examine the relationship between income inequality, poverty, and different types of crime. Our results are consistent with recent research in showing that inequality is unrelated to homicide rates when poverty is controlled. In our multi-level analyses of the International Crime Victimization Survey we find that inequality is unrelated to assault, robbery, burglary, and theft when poverty is controlled. We argue that there are also theoretical reasons to doubt that the level of income inequality of a country affects the likelihood of criminal behaviour.

Keywords: Cross-national criminology; ICVS; homicide; income inequality; poverty.

© London School of Economics and Political Science 2014.

PubMed Disclaimer

Similar articles

  • Is poverty the mother of crime? Evidence from homicide rates in China. Dong B, Egger PH, Guo Y. Dong B, et al. PLoS One. 2020 May 18;15(5):e0233034. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0233034. eCollection 2020. PLoS One. 2020. PMID: 32422646 Free PMC article.
  • Crime: social disorganization and relative deprivation. Kawachi I, Kennedy BP, Wilkinson RG. Kawachi I, et al. Soc Sci Med. 1999 Mar;48(6):719-31. doi: 10.1016/s0277-9536(98)00400-6. Soc Sci Med. 1999. PMID: 10190635
  • The relative contribution of income inequality and imprisonment to the variation in homicide rates among Developed (OECD), South and Central American countries. Nadanovsky P, Cunha-Cruz J. Nadanovsky P, et al. Soc Sci Med. 2009 Nov;69(9):1343-50. doi: 10.1016/j.socscimed.2009.08.013. Epub 2009 Sep 4. Soc Sci Med. 2009. PMID: 19733952
  • Epidemiology of violence and theft in the workplace. Bachman R. Bachman R. Occup Med. 1996 Apr-Jun;11(2):237-41. Occup Med. 1996. PMID: 8936253 Review.
  • The impact of population heterogeneity and income inequality on homicide rates: a cross-national assessment. Chon DS. Chon DS. Int J Offender Ther Comp Criminol. 2012 Aug;56(5):730-48. doi: 10.1177/0306624X11414813. Epub 2011 Jul 4. Int J Offender Ther Comp Criminol. 2012. PMID: 21729910 Review.
  • Modeling the role of police corruption in the reduction of organized crime: Mexico as a case study. Aldana A, Larralde H, Aldana M. Aldana A, et al. Sci Rep. 2022 Nov 10;12(1):19233. doi: 10.1038/s41598-022-23630-x. Sci Rep. 2022. PMID: 36357463 Free PMC article.
  • Perceived Neighborhood Crime Safety Moderates the Association Between Racial Discrimination Stress and Chronic Health Conditions Among Hispanic/Latino Adults. Budd EL, Giuliani NR, Kelly NR. Budd EL, et al. Front Public Health. 2021 Feb 15;9:585157. doi: 10.3389/fpubh.2021.585157. eCollection 2021. Front Public Health. 2021. PMID: 33659230 Free PMC article.
  • Disentangling community-level changes in crime trends during the COVID-19 pandemic in Chicago. Campedelli GM, Favarin S, Aziani A, Piquero AR. Campedelli GM, et al. Crime Sci. 2020;9(1):21. doi: 10.1186/s40163-020-00131-8. Epub 2020 Oct 27. Crime Sci. 2020. PMID: 33134029 Free PMC article.
  • Search in MeSH

LinkOut - more resources

Full text sources, other literature sources.

  • scite Smart Citations

full text provider logo

  • Citation Manager

NCBI Literature Resources

MeSH PMC Bookshelf Disclaimer

The PubMed wordmark and PubMed logo are registered trademarks of the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (HHS). Unauthorized use of these marks is strictly prohibited.

To read this content please select one of the options below:

Please note you do not have access to teaching notes, does poverty lead to crime evidence from the united states of america.

International Journal of Social Economics

ISSN : 0306-8293

Article publication date: 7 August 2018

Issue publication date: 25 September 2018

Economic hardship and crime is always a debatable issue in the political economy literature. Some authors define poverty leads to crime some are completely opposite. The purpose of this paper is to find out the impact of poverty on crime in the USA.

Design/methodology/approach

Using time series data of USA over the period from 1965 to 2016, this study applies autoregressive distributed lag approach to identify the effect of poverty on crime.

The outcomes confirm a positive co-integrating relationship between poverty and property crime. It can be argued that poverty ultimately leads property crime in long run in the USA. However, unemployment and GDP exhibit neither long-run nor short-run relationship with property crime and they are not cointegrated for the calculated period.

Research limitations/implications

The subject of this paper helps to explain and analyze the nexus between poverty and crime in the USA.

Practical implications

Government and policymakers should focus more on poverty rather than unemployment alone to control property crime.

Originality/value

This study attempts to identify the consequences of economic hardship and poverty on the crime in the advanced economy like USA.

  • Property crime

Acknowledgements

The authors of this paper have not made their research data set openly available. Any enquiries regarding the data set can be directed to the corresponding author.

Imran, M. , Hosen, M. and Chowdhury, M.A.F. (2018), "Does poverty lead to crime? Evidence from the United States of America", International Journal of Social Economics , Vol. 45 No. 10, pp. 1424-1438. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJSE-04-2017-0167

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2018, Emerald Publishing Limited

Related articles

All feedback is valuable.

Please share your general feedback

Report an issue or find answers to frequently asked questions

Contact Customer Support

Poverty as a Harbinger of Crime

  • Living reference work entry
  • Later version available View entry history
  • First Online: 01 November 2022
  • Cite this living reference work entry

research paper on poverty and crime

  • Oladotun Akanni 8  

Part of the book series: Encyclopedia of the UN Sustainable Development Goals ((ENUNSDG))

36 Accesses

Crime ; Inequality ; Low income ; Population density ; Poverty ; Unemployment

There is no universal definition of poverty because how poverty is defined and measured varies across the world. Perception of poverty or what constitutes poverty depends on the socioeconomic conditions of a particular country. Poverty is complex and multidimensional. Generally, poverty can be ascribed to income deprivation and insufficient resources to meet the minimum and basic necessity of human needs and ensure sustainable livelihoods. Poverty is not just about shortage or paucity of monetary resources but also lack of access to basic social infrastructures like education and healthcare to live a meaningful and decent life. Crime implies any wrongdoing that is liable to punishment in conformity with the law of a country. Simply put, it is the violation of law or an act of lawbreaking. Crimes are committed for various reasons and these include greed, revenge, anger, and envy. Typically,...

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Adebayo AA (2013) Youths’ unemployment and crime in Nigeria: a nexus and implications for national development. Int J Sociol Anthropol 5(8):350–357

Article   Google Scholar  

Adekoya A, Abdul-Razak N (2016) Effect of crime on poverty in Nigeria. Rom Econ Bus Rev 11(2):30–42

Google Scholar  

Adenike ET (2021) Poverty, unemployment and insecurity challenges in Nigeria. Tanzan Econ Rev 11(1):115–136

Ahad M (2016) Nexus between income inequality, crime, inflation and poverty: new evidence from structural breaks for Pakistan. Int J Econ Empir Res 4(3):133–145

Ali A, Bibi C (2020) Public policies, socio-economic environment and crimes in Pakistan: a time series analysis. Bull Bus Econ 9(1):1–11

Altindag DT (2012) Crime and unemployment: evidence from Europe. Int Rev Law Econ 32(1):145–157

Anser MK, Yousaf Z, Nassani AA, Alotaibi SM, Kabbani A, Zaman K (2020) Dynamic linkages between poverty, inequality, crime, and social expenditures in a panel of 16 countries: two-step GMM estimates. Econ Struct 9(43):1–25

Anwer MA, Nasreen S, Shahzadi A (2015) Social and demographic determinants of crime in Pakistan: a panel data analysis of province Punjab. Int J Econ Empir Res 3(9):440–447

Ayhan F, Bursa N (2019) Unemployment and crime nexus in European Union countries: a panel data analysis. J Adm Sci 17(34):465–484

Baharom AH, Habibullah MS (2008) Is crime cointegrated with income and unemployment?: a panel data analysis on selected European countries. Available at: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/11927/1/MPRA_paper_11927.pdf

Berrebi D (2011) Effects of poverty on society, health, children and violence. Available at: https://www.restlessstories.com/poverties/effects-of-poverty

Bharadwaj A (2014) Is poverty the mother of crime? Empirical evidence of the impact of socioeconomic factors on crime in India. Atl Rev Econ 1:1–37

Bhorat H, Lilenstein A, Monnakgotla J, Thornton A, Van Der Zee K (2017) The socio-economic determinants of crime in South Africa: an empirical assessment. Development Policy Research Unit working paper 201704, pp 1–38

Bignon V, Caroli E, Galbiati R (2014) Stealing to survive? Crime and income shocks in 19th century France. IZA – Institute for the Study of Labor, IZA DP no. 8531, pp 1–59

Bjerk D (2009) Thieves, thugs, and neighborhood poverty. IZA – Institute of Labor Economics. IZA DP no. 4470, pp 1–35

Buonanno P (2003) The socioeconomic determinants of crime. A review of the literature. Available at: http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.504.2832&rep=rep1&type=pdf

Cheteni P, Mah G, Yohane YK (2018) Drug-related crime and poverty in South Africa. Cogent Econ Finance 6(1):1–16. https://doi.org/10.1080/23322039.2018.1534528

Corvalan A, Pazzona M (2019) The ambiguous effects of inequality: the case of crime. Available at: https://sistemas.colmex.mx/Reportes/LACEALAMES/LACEA-LAMES2019_paper_746.pdf

Corvalan A, Pazzona M (n.d.) Does inequality really increase crime? Theory and evidence. Available at: http://www.ecineq.org/ecineq_paris19/papers_EcineqPSE/paper_122.pdf

Dalberis R (2015) Extreme levels of poverty and inequality may lead to equally high levels of social conflict and crime. M.A. thesis, City University of New York (CUNY)

Development Initiatives (2021) Poverty trends: global, regional and national. Available at: https://devinit.org/documents/1100/Poverty_trends_-_global_regional_and_national_-_November_2021.pdf

Dong B, Egger PH, Guo Y (2020) Is poverty the mother of crime? Evidence from homicide rates in China. PLoS One 15(5):1–22

Article   CAS   Google Scholar  

Duque M, McKnight A (2019) Understanding the relationship between inequalities and poverty: mechanisms associated with crime, the legal system and punitive sanctions. CASE paper 215/LIP paper 6. Available at: https://sticerd.lse.ac.uk/dps/case/cp/casepaper215.pdf

ECLAC (2008) Exploring policy linkages between poverty, crime and violence: a look at three Caribbean states. Available at: https://www.cepal.org/sites/default/files/publication/files/5060/S0800466_en.pdf

ECLAC (2022) Social panorama of Latin America, 2021. Available at: https://repositorio.cepal.org/bitstream/handle/11362/47719/1/S2100654_en.pdf

Eurostat (2021) One in five people in the EU at risk of poverty or social exclusion. Available at: https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/products-eurostat-news/-/edn-20211015-1

Fafchamps M, Minten B (2006) Crime, transitory poverty, and isolation: evidence from Madagascar. Econ Dev Cult Chang 54(3):579–603

Gaviria A, Pages C (2002) Patterns of crime victimization in Latin American cities. J Dev Econ 67(1):181–203

Haider A, Ali A (2015) Socio-economic determinants of crimes: a cross-sectional study of Punjab districts. Int J Econ Empir Res 3(11):550–560

Hamzah SNZ, Lau E (2013) The role of social factors in explaining crime. Theor Appl Econ 6(583):99–118

Hooghe M, Vanhoutte B, Hardyns W, Bircan T (2010) Unemployment, inequality, poverty and crime: spatial distribution patterns of criminal acts in Belgium, 2001–06. Br J Criminol 51(1):1–20

Hsieh CC, Pugh MD (1993) Poverty, income inequality, and violent crime: a meta-analysis of recent aggregate data studies. Crim Justice Rev 18(2):182–202

Igbinedion SO, Ebomoyi I (2017) Socio-economic determinants of crime: further evidence from Nigeria. Ann Univ Petroşani Econ 17(1):101–114

Ikejiaku BV (2012) Poverty-conflict nexus: the contentious issue revisited. Eur J Sustain Dev 1(2):127–150

Imran M, Hosen M, Chowdhury MAF (2018) Does poverty lead to crime? Evidence from the United States of America. Int J Soc Econ 45(10):1424–1438

Iyer L, Topalova P (2014) Poverty and crime: evidence from rainfall and trade shocks in India. Harvard Business School working paper, 14-067, pp 1–46

Kelly M (2000) Inequality and crime. Rev Econ Stat 82(4):530–539

Kingston S, Webster C (2015) The most “undeserving” of all? How poverty drives young men to victimisation and crime. Available at: https://eprints.lancs.ac.uk/id/eprint/75784/1/JPSJ_Article_September_2015_final_V5_sent.pdf

Lobonţ Q-R, Nicolescu AC, Moldovan NC, Kuloğlu A (2017) The effect of socioeconomic factors on crime rates in Romania: a macro-level analysis. Econ Res 30(1):91–111

Machin S, Meghir C (2000) Crime and economic incentives. J Hum Resour 39(4):958–979

Maddah M (2013) The effect of unemployment and income inequality on crimes, a time series analysis. Int J Econ Res 4(2):37–42

Malik M, Rabia M, Imran M, Irshad R, Khalid KB (2019) Poverty leads to crime: a case study in GC women university, Sialkot. In: Proc. 15th Islamic countries conference on statistical sciences, Lahore, Pakistan, 21–24 December, 34, pp 107–117

McKeown JE (1949) Poverty, race and crime. J Crim Law Criminol 39(4):480–484

Mehlum H, Miguel E, Torvik R (2006) Poverty and crime in 19th century Germany. Journal of Urban Economics (59)3:370–388.

Ngutu JA (2014) The influence of poverty on crime among the Abanyole of Emuhaya District, Western Kenya. J Humanit Soc Sci 19(4):108–142

Nilsson A (2004) Income inequality and crime: the case of Sweden. IFAU working paper, 2004–6, pp 1–36

Odumosu O (1999) Social costs of poverty: the case of crime in Nigeria. J Soc Dev Afr 14(2):71–85

Olojede D (2015) Ten big ideas. TELL, 23 November, p 43

Omotor DG (2010) Demographic and socio-economic determinants of crimes in Nigeria (a panel data analysis). Available at: http://www.digitalcommons.www.na-businesspress.com/JABE/Jabe111/GodwinWeb.pdf

Osunyikanmi AF (2014) Interrogating the influence of poverty on insecurity in Nigeria. Int J Humanit Soc Sci 4(12):221–227

Owusu G (2016) Introduction: urban crime and poverty nexus. Ghana J Geogr Spec Issue 8(1):1–10

Oyelade AO (2019) Determinants of crime in Nigeria from economic and socioeconomic perspectives: a macro-level analysis. Int J Health Econ Policy 4(1):20–28

Pablo F, Daniel L, Norman L (2000) What causes violent crime? Eur Econ Rev 46:1323–1357

Papaioannou K (2017) Hunger makes a thief of any man: poverty and crime in British colonial Asia. Eur Rev Econ Hist 21:1–28

Patterson EB (1991) Poverty, income inequality, and community crime rates. Criminology 29(4):755–776

Piana V (2006) Poverty. Available at: http://www.economicswebinstitute.org/glossary/poverty.htm

Presidential Committee on the North East Initiative (PCNI) (2016) Rebuilding the North East: the Buhari plan (vol I). Available at: https://www.refworld.org/pdfid/5b42ec184.pdf

Quednau J (2021) How are violent crime rates in U.S. cities affected by poverty? Park Place Econ 28(1):1–24

Rufrancos HG, Power M, Pickett KE, Wilkinson R (2013) Income inequality and crime: a review and explanation of the time-series evidence. Soc Criminol 1(103):1–9. https://doi.org/10.4172/2375-4435.1000103

Shubert C (2003) Female crime and poverty: stolen opportunities. MAIS 701 project, University of Athabasca

Taylor B (2006) Poverty and crime. Available at: http://economics.fundamentalfinance.com/povertycrime

Tesemma G (2017) The nexus between urban crime and poverty: the case of Addis Ababa city administration. M.A. dissertation, Addis Ababa University

Traxler C, Burhop C (2010) Poverty and crime in 19th century Germany: a reassessment. Available at: https://homepage.coll.mpg.de/pdf_dat/2010_35online.pdf

Ucha C (2010) Poverty in Nigeria: some dimensions and contributing factors. Glob Major E-J 1(1):46–56

United Nations (n.d.) Poverty eradication. Available at: https://www.un.org/development/desa/socialperspectiveondevelopment/issues/poverty-eradication.html

Uyang FA, Festus N, Bassey GE (2016) Socio-economic status of youth and involvement in criminal activities in Calabar Metropolis of Cross River State, Nigeria. Int J Humanit Soc Sci Educ 3(1):79–83

Vollaard B, Van Ours JC (2011) Does regulation of built-in security reduce crime? Evidence from a natural experiment. Econ J 121:485–450

Wadsworth TP (2001) Employment, crime, and context: a multi-level analysis of the relationship between work and crime. Ph.D. thesis, University of Washington

Webster C, Kingston S (2014) Anti-poverty strategies for the UK: poverty and crime review. Centre for Applied Social Research (CeASR). Available at: https://eprints.leedsbeckett.ac.uk/id/eprint/849/7/JRF%20Poverty%20and%20Crime%20Review%20June%202016.pdf

Whitworth A (2012) Inequality and crime across England: a multilevel modelling approach. Soc Policy Soc 11(1):27–40

Wikström P-OH, Treiber K (2016) Social disadvantage and crime: a criminological puzzle. Am Behav Sci 60(10):1232–1259

World Bank (2021) Poverty and shared prosperity 2020: reversals of fortune. Available at: https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/34496/9781464816024.pdf?sequence=33&isAllowed=y

World Bank, NBS (2018) Conflict and violence in Nigeria: results from the North East, North Central, and South South zones. Available at: https://documents1.worldbank.org/curated/en/111851538025875054/pdf/130198-WP-P160999-PUBLIC-26-9-2018-14-42-49-ConflictViolenceinNigeriaResultsfromNENCSSzonesFinal.pdf

World Vision (2021) Global poverty: facts, FAQs, and how to help. Available at: https://www.worldvision.org/sponsorship-news-stories/global-poverty-facts#multidimensional

WPI Economics (2021) London’s poverty profile 2021: covid-19 and poverty in London. Available at: http://wpieconomics.com/site/wp-content/uploads/2021/04/Londons_Poverty_Profile_2021_-_COVID19__poverty_in_London.pdf

Wu D, Wu Z (2011) Crime, inequality and unemployment in England and Wales. Appl Econ 2011:1–28

Yaacoub S (2017) Poverty, inequality and the social causes of crime: a study between United States and Europe. Int J Sci Res 6(10):629–634

Yang Z (2019) Measurement of childhood poverty in the United States and its enduring influences. J Sociol Soc Welf 46(2):47–73

Zaman K (2018) Crime-poverty nexus: an intellectual survey. Forensic Res Criminol Int J 6(5):327–329

Zaman S, Khan AU (2021) Dynamics of crime rate, income inequality and urbanization across regimes in Pakistan. Indian J Econ Dev 9:1–15

Download references

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

International Development Consultant, Abuja, Nigeria

Oladotun Akanni

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Editor information

Editors and affiliations.

European School of Sustainability, Hamburg University of Applied Sciences, Hamburg, Hamburg, Germany

Walter Leal Filho

Center for Neuroscience & Cell Biology, University of Coimbra, Coimbra, Portugal

Anabela Marisa Azul

Faculty of Engineering and Architecture, Passo Fundo University Faculty of Engineering and Architecture, Passo Fundo, Brazil

Luciana Brandli

HAW Hamburg, Hamburg, Hamburg, Germany

Amanda Lange Salvia

Istinye University, Istanbul, Turkey

Pinar Gökcin Özuyar

Liverpool Business School, Liverpool John Moores University, Liverpool, UK

Section Editor information

School of Property, Construction and Project Management, RMIT University, Melbourne, VIC, Australia

Usha Iyer-Raniga Ph.D

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2023 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this entry

Cite this entry.

Akanni, O. (2023). Poverty as a Harbinger of Crime. In: Leal Filho, W., Azul, A.M., Brandli, L., Lange Salvia, A., Özuyar, P.G., Wall, T. (eds) No Poverty. Encyclopedia of the UN Sustainable Development Goals. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-69625-6_53-1

Download citation

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-69625-6_53-1

Received : 17 June 2022

Accepted : 06 July 2022

Published : 01 November 2022

Publisher Name : Springer, Cham

Print ISBN : 978-3-319-69625-6

Online ISBN : 978-3-319-69625-6

eBook Packages : Springer Reference Earth and Environm. Science Reference Module Physical and Materials Science Reference Module Earth and Environmental Sciences

  • Publish with us

Policies and ethics

Chapter history

DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-69625-6_53-2

DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-69625-6_53-1

  • Find a journal
  • Track your research

U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

The .gov means it’s official. Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

The site is secure. The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

  • Publications
  • Account settings

The PMC website is updating on October 15, 2024. Learn More or Try it out now .

  • Advanced Search
  • Journal List

Logo of springeropen

The Social Consequences of Poverty: An Empirical Test on Longitudinal Data

Carina mood.

Institute for Futures Studies, Box 591, 101 31 Stockholm, Sweden

Swedish Institute for Social Research (SOFI), Stockholm University, Stockholm, Sweden

Jan O. Jonsson

Nuffield College, OX1 1NF Oxford, England, UK

Poverty is commonly defined as a lack of economic resources that has negative social consequences, but surprisingly little is known about the importance of economic hardship for social outcomes. This article offers an empirical investigation into this issue. We apply panel data methods on longitudinal data from the Swedish Level-of-Living Survey 2000 and 2010 (n = 3089) to study whether poverty affects four social outcomes—close social relations (social support), other social relations (friends and relatives), political participation, and activity in organizations. We also compare these effects across five different poverty indicators. Our main conclusion is that poverty in general has negative effects on social life. It has more harmful effects for relations with friends and relatives than for social support; and more for political participation than organizational activity. The poverty indicator that shows the greatest impact is material deprivation (lack of cash margin), while the most prevalent poverty indicators—absolute income poverty, and especially relative income poverty—appear to have the least effect on social outcomes.

Introduction

According to the most influential definitions, poverty is seen as a lack of economic resources that have negative social consequences—this is in fact a view that dominates current theories of poverty (Townsend 1979 ; Sen 1983 ; UN 1995 ), and also has a long heritage (Smith 1776 /1976). The idea is that even when people have food, clothes, and shelter, economic problems lead to a deterioration of social relations and participation. Being poor is about not being able to partake in society on equal terms with others, and therefore in the long run being excluded by fellow citizens or withdrawing from social and civic life because of a lack of economic resources, typically in combination with the concomitant shame of not being able to live a life like them (e.g., Sen 1983 ). Economic hardship affects the standard of life, consumption patterns, and leisure time activities, and this is directly or indirectly related to the possibility of making or maintaining friends or acquaintances: poverty is revealed by not having appropriate clothes, or a car; by not being able to afford vacation trips, visits to the restaurant, or hosting dinner parties (e.g., Mack and Lansley 1985 ; Callan et al. 1993 )—in short, low incomes prevent the poor from living a life in “decency” (Galbraith 1958 ).

The relational nature of poverty is also central to the social exclusion literature, which puts poverty in a larger perspective of multiple disadvantages and their interrelationships (Hills et al. 2002 , Rodgers et al. 1995 ; Room 1995 ). While there are different definitions of the social exclusion concept, the literature is characterized by a move from distributional to relational concerns (Gore 1995 ) and by an emphasis on the importance of social integration and active participation in public life. The inability of living a decent or “ordinary” social life may in this perspective erode social networks, social relations, and social participation, potentially setting off a downward spiral of misfortune (Paugam 1995 ) reinforcing disadvantages in several domains of life. This perspective on poverty and social exclusion is essentially sociological: the playing field of the private economy is social. It is ultimately about individuals’ relations with other people—not only primary social relations, with kin and friends, but extending to secondary relations reflected by participation in the wider community, such as in organizations and in political life (UN 1995 ).

Despite the fact that the social consequences of limited economic resources are central to modern perspectives on poverty and marginalization, this relation is surprisingly seldom studied empirically. Qualitative research on the poor give interesting examples on how the negative effects of poverty works, and portray the way that economic problems are transformed into social ones (Ridge and Millar 2011 ; Attree 2006 ). Such studies, however, have too small sample sizes to generalize to the population, and they cannot tell us much about the range of the problem. The (relatively few) studies that have addressed the association between poverty and social outcomes on larger scale tend to verify that the poor have worse social relations (Böhnke 2008 ; Jonsson and Östberg 2004 ; Levitas 2006 ), but Barnes et al. ( 2002 ) did not find any noteworthy association between poverty (measured as relative income poverty, using the 60 %-limit) and social relations or social isolation. Dahl et al. ( 2008 ) found no relation between poverty and friendships, but report less participation in civic organizations among the poor. All these studies have however been limited to cross-sectional data or hampered by methodological shortcomings, and therefore have not been able to address the separation of selection effects from potentially causal ones.

Our aim in this study is to make good these omissions. We use longitudinal data from the Swedish Level of Living Surveys (LNU) 2000 and 2010 to study how falling into poverty, or rising from it, is associated with outcomes in terms of primary and secondary social relations, including participation in civil society. These panel data make it possible to generalize the results to the Swedish adult population (19–65 in 2000; 29–75 in 2010), to address the issue of causality, and to estimate how strong the relation between economic vulnerability and social outcomes is. Because the data provide us with the possibility of measuring poverty in several ways, we are also able to address the question using different—alternative or complementary—indicators. Poverty is measured as economic deprivation (lack of cash margin, self-reported economic problems), income poverty (absolute and relative), and long-term poverty, respectively. The primary, or core, social outcomes are indicated by having social support if needed, and by social relations with friends and relatives. We expand our analysis to secondary, or fringe, social outcomes in terms of participation in social life at large, such as in civil society: our indicators here include the participation in organizations and in political life.

Different Dimensions/Definitions of Poverty

In modern welfare states, the normal take on the issue of poverty is to regard it as the relative lack of economic resources, that is, to define the poor in relation to their fellow citizens in the same country at the same time. Three approaches dominate the scholarly literature today. The first takes as a point of departure the income deemed necessary for living a life on par with others, or that makes possible an “acceptable” living standard—defined as the goods and services judged necessary, often on the basis of consumer or household budget studies. This usage of a poverty threshold is often (somewhat confusingly) called absolute income poverty , and is most common in North America (cf. Corak 2006 for a review), although most countries have poverty lines defined for different kinds of social benefits. In Europe and in the OECD, the convention is instead to use versions of relative income poverty , defining as poor those whose incomes fall well behind the median income in the country in question (European Union using 60 % and OECD 50 % of the median as the threshold). As an alternative to using purchasing power (as in the “absolute” measure), this relative measure defines poverty by income inequality in the bottom half of the income distribution (Atkinson et al. 2002 ; OECD 2008 ).

The third approach argues that income measures are too indirect; poverty should instead be indicated directly by the lack of consumer products and services that are necessary for an acceptable living standard (Mack and Lansley 1985 ; Ringen 1988 ; Townsend 1979 ). This approach often involves listing a number of possessions and conditions, such as having a car, washing machine, modern kitchen; and being able to dine out sometimes, to have the home adequately heated and mended, to have sufficient insurances, and so on. An elaborate version includes information on what people in general see as necessities, what is often termed “consensual” poverty (e.g., Mack and Lansley 1985 ; Gordon et al. 2000 ; Halleröd 1995 ; van den Bosch 2001 ). Other direct indicators include the ability to cover unforeseen costs (cash margin) and subjective definitions of poverty (e.g., van den Bosch 2001 ). The direct approach to poverty has gained in popularity and measures of economic/material deprivation and consensual poverty are used in several recent and contemporary comparative surveys such as ECHP (Whelan et al. 2003 ) and EU-SILC (e.g., UNICEF 2012 ; Nolan and Whelan 2011 ).

It is often pointed out that, due to the often quite volatile income careers of households, the majority of poverty episodes are short term and the group that is identified as poor in the cross-section therefore tends to be rather diluted (Bane and Ellwood 1986 ; Duncan et al. 1993 ). Those who suffer most from the downsides of poverty are, it could be argued, instead the long-term, persistent, or chronically poor, and there is empirical evidence that those who experience more years in poverty also are more deprived of a “common lifestyle” (Whelan et al. 2003 ). Poverty persistence has been defined in several ways, such as having spent a given number of years below a poverty threshold, or having an average income over a number of years that falls under the poverty line (e.g., Duncan and Rodgers 1991 ; Rodgers and Rodgers 1993 ). The persistently poor can only be detected with any precision in longitudinal studies, and typically on the basis of low incomes, as data covering repeated measures of material deprivation are uncommon.

For the purposes of this study, it is not essential to nominate the best or most appropriate poverty measure. The measures outlined above, while each having some disadvantage, all provide plausible theoretical grounds for predicting negative social outcomes. Low incomes, either in “absolute” or relative terms, may inhibit social activities and participation because these are costly (e.g., having decent housing, needing a car, paying membership fees, entrance tickets, or new clothes). Economic deprivation, often indicated by items or habits that are directly relevant to social life, is also a valid representation of a lack of resources. Lastly, to be in long-term poverty is no doubt a worse condition than being in shorter-term poverty.

It is worth underlining that we see different measures of poverty as relevant indicators despite the fact that the overlap between them often is surprisingly small (Bradshaw and Finch 2003 ). The lack of overlap is not necessarily a problem, as different people may have different configurations of economic problems but share in common many of the experiences of poverty—experiences, we argue, that are (in theory at least) all likely to lead to adverse social outcomes. Whether this is the case or not is one of the questions that we address, but if previous studies on child poverty are of any guidance, different definitions of poverty may show surprisingly similar associations with a number of outcomes (Jonsson and Östberg 2004 ).

What are the Likely Social Consequences of Poverty?

We have concluded that poverty is, according to most influential poverty definitions, manifested in the social sphere. This connects with the idea of Veblen ( 1899 ) of the relation between consumption and social status. What you buy and consume—clothes, furniture, vacation trips—in part define who you are, which group you aspire to belong to, and what view others will have of you. Inclusion into and exclusion from status groups and social circles are, in this view, dependent on economic resources as reflected in consumption patterns. While Veblen was mostly concerned about the rich and their conspicuous consumption, it is not difficult to transfer these ideas to the less fortunate: the poor are under risk of exclusion, of losing their social status and identity, and perhaps also, therefore, their friends. It is however likely that this is a process that differs according to outcome, with an unknown time-lag.

If, as outlined above, we can speak of primary and secondary social consequences, the former should include socializing with friends, but also more intimate relations. Our conjecture is that the closer the relation, the less affected is it by poverty, simply because intimate social bonds are characterized by more unconditional personal relations, typically not requiring costs to uphold.

When it comes to the secondary social consequences, we move outside the realm of closer interpersonal relations to acquaintances and the wider social network, and to the (sometimes relatively anonymous) participation in civil or political life. This dimension of poverty lies at the heart of the social exclusion perspective, which strongly emphasizes the broader issues of societal participation and civic engagement, vital to democratic societies. It is also reflected in the United Nation’s definition, following the Copenhagen summit in 1995, where “overall poverty” in addition to lack of economic resources is said to be “…characterized by lack of participation in decision-making and in civil, social, and cultural life” (UN 1995 , p. 57). Poverty may bring about secondary social consequences because such participation is costly—as in the examples of travel, need for special equipment, or membership fees—but also because of psychological mechanisms, such as lowered self-esteem triggering disbelief in civic and political activities, and a general passivity leading to decreased organizational and social activities overall. If processes like these exist there is a risk of a “downward spiral of social exclusion” where unemployment leads to poverty and social isolation, which in turn reduce the chances of re-gaining a footing in the labour market (Paugam 1995 ).

What theories of poverty and social exclusion postulate is, in conclusion, that both what we have called primary and secondary social relations will be negatively affected by economic hardship—the latter supposedly more than the former. Our strategy in the following is to test this basic hypothesis by applying multivariate panel-data analyses on longitudinal data. In this way, we believe that we can come further than previous studies towards estimating causal effects, although, as is the case in social sciences, the causal relation must remain preliminary due to the nature of observational data.

Data and Definitions

We use the two most recent waves of the Swedish Level-of-living Survey, conducted in 2000 and 2010 on random (1/1000) samples of adult Swedes, aged 18–75. 1 The attrition rate is low, with 84 % of panel respondents remaining from 2000 to 2010. This is one of the few data sets from which we can get over-time measures of both poverty and social outcomes for a panel that is representative of the adult population (at the first time point, t 0 )—in addition, there is annual income information from register data between the waves. The panel feature obviously restricts the age-groups slightly (ages 19–65 in 2000; 29–75 in 2010), the final number of analyzed cases being between 2995 and 3144, depending on the number of missing cases on the respective poverty measure and social outcome variable. For ease of interpretation and comparison of effect sizes, we have constructed all social outcome variables and poverty variables to be dichotomous (0/1). 2

In constructing poverty variables, we must balance theoretical validity with the need to have group sizes large enough for statistical analysis. For example, we expand the absolute poverty measure to include those who received social assistance any time during the year. As social assistance recipients receive this benefit based on having an income below a poverty line that is similar to the one we use, this seems justifiable. In other cases, however, group sizes are small but we find no theoretically reasonable way of making the variables more inclusive, meaning that some analyses cannot be carried out in full detail.

Our income poverty measures are based on register data and are thus free from recall error or misreporting, but—as the proponents of deprivation measures point out—income poverty measures are indirect measures of hardship. The deprivation measure is more direct, but self-reporting always carries a risk of subjectivity in the assessment. To the extent that changes in one’s judgment of the economic situation depend on changes in non-economic factors that are also related to social relations, the deprivation measure will give upwardly biased estimates. 3 As there is no general agreement about whether income or deprivation definitions are superior, our use of several definitions is a strength because the results will give an overall picture that is not sensitive to potential limitations in any one measure. In addition, we are able to see whether results vary systematically across commonly used definitions.

Poverty Measures

  • Cash margin whether the respondent can raise a given sum of money in a week, if necessary (in 2000, the sum was 12,000 SEK; in 2010, 14,000 SEK, the latter sum corresponding to approximately 1600 Euro, 2200 USD, or 1400 GBP in 2013 currency rates). For those who answer in the affirmative, there is a follow-up question of how this can be done: by (a) own/household resources, (b) borrowing.
  • Economic crisis Those who claim that they have had problems meeting costs for rent, food, bills, etc. during the last 12 months (responded “yes” to a yes/no alternative).
  • Absolute poverty is defined as either (a) having a disposable family income below a poverty threshold or (b) receiving social assistance, both assessed in 1999 (for the survey 2000) or 2009 (for the survey 2010). The poverty line varies by family type/composition according to a commonly used calculation of household necessities (Jansson 2000 ). This “basket” of goods and services is intended to define an acceptable living standard, and was originally constructed for calculating an income threshold for social assistance, with addition of estimated costs for housing and transport. The threshold is adjusted for changes in the Consumer Price Index, using 2010 as the base year. In order to get analyzable group sizes, we classify anyone with an income below 1.25 times this threshold as poor. Self-employed are excluded because their nominal incomes are often a poor indicator of their economic standard.
  • Deprived and income poor A combination of the indicator of economic deprivation and the indicator of absolute poverty. The poor are defined as those who are economically deprived and in addition are either absolute income-poor or have had social assistance some time during the last calendar year.
  • Long - term poor are defined as those interviewed in 2010 (2000) who had an equivalized disposable income that fell below the 1.25 absolute poverty threshold (excluding self-employed) or who received social assistance in 2009 (1999), and who were in this situation for at least two of the years 2000–2008 (1990–1998). The long-term poor (coded 1) are contrasted to the non-poor (coded 0), excluding the short-term poor (coded missing) in order to distinguish whether long-term poverty is particularly detrimental (as compared to absolute poverty in general).
  • Relative poverty is defined, according to the EU standard, as having a disposable equivalized income that is lower than 60 % of the median income in Sweden the year in question (EU 2005). 4 As for absolute poverty, this variable is based on incomes the year prior to the survey year. Self-employed are excluded.

Social and Participation Outcomes

Primary (core) social relations.

  • Social support The value 1 (has support) is given to those who have answered in the positive to three questions about whether one has a close friend who can help if one (a) gets sick, (b) needs someone to talk to about troubles, or (c) needs company. Those who lack support in at least one of these respects are coded 0 (lack of support).
  • Frequent social relations This variable is based on four questions about how often one meets (a) relatives and (b) friends, either (i) at ones’ home or (ii) at the home of those one meets, with the response set being “yes, often”, “sometimes”, and “no, never”. Respondents are defined as having frequent relations (1) if they have at least one “often” of the four possible and no “never”, 5 and 0 otherwise.

Secondary (fringe) Social Relations/Participation

  • Political participation : Coded 1 (yes) if one during the last 12 months actively participated (held an elected position or was at a meeting) in a trade union or a political party, and 0 (no) otherwise. 6
  • Organizational activity : Coded 1 (yes) if one is a member of an organization and actively participate in its activities at least once in a year, and 0 (no) otherwise.

Control Variables

  • Age (in years)
  • Educational qualifications in 2010 (five levels according to a standard schema used by Statistics Sweden (1985), entered as dummy variables)
  • Civil status distinguishes between single and cohabiting/married persons, and is used as a time-varying covariate (TVC) where we register any changes from couple to single and vice versa.
  • Immigrant origin is coded 1 if both parents were born in any country outside Sweden, 0 otherwise.
  • Labour market status is also used as a TVC, with four values indicating labour market participation (yes/no) in 2000 and 2010, respectively.
  • Global self - rated health in 2000, with three response alternatives: Good, bad, or in between. 7

Table  1 shows descriptive statistics for the 2 years we study, 2000 and 2010 (percentages in the upper panel; averages, standard deviations, max and min values in the lower panel). Recall that the sample is longitudinal with the same respondents appearing in both years. This means, naturally, that the sample ages 10 years between the waves, the upper age limit being pushed up from 65 to 75. Both the change over years and the ageing of the sample have repercussions for their conditions: somewhat more have poor health, for example, fewer lack social support but more lack frequent social relations, and more are single in 2010 (where widows are a growing category). The group has however improved their economic conditions, with a sizeable reduction in poverty rates. Most of the changes are in fact period effects, and it is particularly obvious for the change in poverty—in 2000 people still suffered from the deep recession in Sweden that begun in 1991 and started to turn in 1996/97 (Jonsson et al. 2010 ), while the most recent international recession (starting in 2008/09) did not affect Sweden that much.

Table 1

Descriptive statistics of dependent and independent variables in the LNU panel

Categorical variables% in 2000% in 2010N
Social support93953150
Frequent social relations89843157
Civic participation (organizations)52443139
Political participation27243157
Economically deprived15103083
Poor (“absolute”)1563156
Poor (relative)19103139
Long-term poor/social assistance1253156
Deprived + income-poor/social assistance733082
Unemployed533153
Woman493157
Single25293157
Immigrant origin113157
3149
Comprehensive school15
Vocational secondary28
Academic upper secondary17
Short-cycle tertiary16
University degree24
3157
Good7875
In between1820
Poor45
Metric variableMeanStddevMinMaxN
Age 2010521329753157

N for variables used as change variables pertains to non-missing observations in both 2000 and 2010

The overall decrease in poverty masks changes that our respondents experienced between 2000 and 2010: Table  2 reveals these for the measure of economic deprivation, showing the outflow (row) percentages and the total percentages (and the number of respondents in parentheses). It is evident that there was quite a lot of mobility out of poverty between the years (61 % left), but also a very strong relative risk of being found in poverty in 2010 among those who were poor in 2000 (39 vs. 5 % of those who were non-poor in 2000). Of all our respondents, the most common situation was to be non-poor both years (81 %), while few were poor on both occasions (6 %). Table  2 also demonstrates some small cell numbers: 13.3 % of the panel (9.4 % + 3.9 %), or a good 400 cases, changed poverty status, and these cases are crucial for identifying our models. As in many panel studies based on survey data, this will inevitably lead to some problems with large standard errors and difficulties in arriving at statistically significant and precise estimates; but to preview the findings, our results are surprisingly consistent all the same.

Table 2

Mobility in poverty (measured as economic deprivation) in Sweden between 2000 and 2010

Poor in 2010Not poor in 2010Total
Row %39.160.9100.0
Total %6.09.415.4
(n)(186)(290)(476)
Row %4.695.4100.0
Total %3.980.784.6
(n)(119)(2488)(2607)
9.990.1100.0
(n)(305)(2778)(3083)

Outflow percentage (row %), total percentage, and number of cases (in parentheses). LNU panel 2000–2010

We begin with showing descriptive results of how poverty is associated with our outcome variables, using the economic deprivation measure of poverty. 8 Figure  1 confirms that those who are poor have worse social relationships and participate less in political life and in organizations. Poverty is thus connected with both primary and secondary social relations.

An external file that holds a picture, illustration, etc.
Object name is 11205_2015_983_Fig1_HTML.jpg

The relation between poverty (measured as economic deprivation) and social relations/participation in Sweden, LNU 2010. N = 5271

The descriptive picture in Fig.  1 does not tell us anything about the causal nature of the relation between poverty and social outcomes, only that such a relation exists, and that it is in the predicted direction: poor people have weaker social relations, less support, and lower levels of political and civic participation. Our task now is to apply more stringent statistical models to test whether the relation we have uncovered is likely to be of a causal nature. This means that we must try to rid the association of both the risk for reverse causality—that, for example, a weaker social network leads to poverty—and the risk that there is a common underlying cause of both poverty and social outcomes, such as poor health or singlehood.

The Change Model

First, as we have panel data, we can study the difference in change across two time-points T (called t 0 and t 1 , respectively) in an outcome variable (e.g., social relations), between groups (i.e. those who changed poverty status versus those who did not). The respondents are assigned to either of these groups on the grounds of entering or leaving poverty; in the first case, one group is non-poor at t 0 but experiences poverty at t 1 , and the change in this group is compared to the group consisting of those who are non-poor both at t 0 and t 1 . The question in focus then is: Do social relations in the group entering poverty worsen in relation to the corresponding change in social relations in the group who remains non-poor? Because we have symmetric hypotheses of the effect of poverty on social outcomes—assuming leaving poverty has positive consequences similar to the negative consequences of entering poverty—we also study whether those who exit poverty improve their social outcomes as compared to those remaining poor. We ask, that is, not only what damage falling into poverty might have for social outcomes, but also what “social gains” could be expected for someone who climbs out of poverty.

Thus, in our analyses we use two different “change groups”, poverty leavers and poverty entrants , and two “comparison groups”, constantly poor and never poor , respectively. 9 The setup comparing the change in social outcomes for those who change poverty status and those who do not is analogous to a so-called difference-in-difference design, but as the allocation of respondents to comparison groups and change groups in our data cannot be assumed to be random (as with control groups and treatment groups in experimental designs), we take further measures to approach causal interpretations.

Accounting for the Starting Value of the Dependent Variable

An important indication of the non-randomness of the allocation to the change and comparison groups is that their average values of the social outcomes (i.e. the dependent variable) at t 0 differ systematically: Those who become poor between 2000 and 2010 have on average worse social outcomes already in 2000 than those who stay out of poverty. Similarly, those who stay in poverty both years have on average worse social outcomes than those who have exited poverty in 2010. In order to further reduce the impact of unobserved variables, we therefore make all comparisons of changes in social outcomes between t 0 and t 1 for fixed t 0 values of both social outcome and poverty status.

As we use dichotomous outcome variables, we get eight combinations of poverty and outcome states (2 × 2 × 2 = 8), and four direct strategic comparisons:

  • Poverty leavers versus constantly poor, positive social outcome in 2000 , showing if those who exit poverty have a higher chance of maintaining the positive social outcome than those who stay in poverty
  • Poverty leavers versus constantly poor, negative social outcome in 2000 , showing if those who exit poverty have a higher chance of improvement in the social outcome than those who stay in poverty
  • Poverty entrants versus never poor, positive social outcome in 2000 , showing if those who enter poverty have a higher risk of deterioration in the social outcome than those who stay out of poverty, and
  • Poverty entrants versus never poor, negative social outcome in 2000 , showing if those who enter poverty have a lower chance of improvement in the social outcome.

Thus, we hold the initial social situation and poverty status fixed, letting only the poverty in 2010 vary. 10 The analytical strategy is set out in Table  3 , showing estimates of the probability to have frequent social relations in 2010, for poverty defined (as in Table  2 and Fig.  1 above) as economic deprivation.

Table 3

Per cent with frequent social relations in “comparison” and “change” groups in 2000 and 2010, according to initial value on social relations in 2000 and poverty (measured as economic deprivation) in 2000 and 2010

Non-frequent social relations 2000Frequent social relations 2000
0–0 (never poor)0.590.90
0–1 (became poor)0.520.72
−0.07−0.17
1–1 (constantly poor)0.390.72
1–0 (escaped poverty)0.720.86
0.330.14

LNU panel 2000–2010. N = 3083

The figures in Table  3 should be read like this: 0.59 in the upper left cell means that among those who were poor neither in 2000 nor in 2010 (“never poor”, or 0–0), and who had non-frequent social relations to begin with, 59 % had frequent social relations in 2010. Among those never poor who instead started out with more frequent social relations, 90 per cent had frequent social relations in 2010. This difference (59 vs. 90) tells us either that the initial conditions were important (weak social relations can be inherently difficult to improve) or that there is heterogeneity within the group of never poor people, such as some having (to us perhaps unobserved) characteristics that support relation building while others have not.

Because our strategy is to condition on the initial situation in order to minimize the impact of initial conditions and unobserved heterogeneity, we focus on the comparisons across columns. If we follow each column downwards, that is, for a given initial social outcome (weak or not weak social relations, respectively) it is apparent that the outcome is worse for the “poverty entrants” in comparison with the “never poor” (upper three lines). Comparing the change group [those who became poor (0–1)] with the comparison group [never poor (0–0)] for those who started out with weak social relations (left column), the estimated probability of frequent social relations in 2010 is 7 % points lower for those who became poor. Among those who started out with frequent relations, those who became poor have a 17 % points lower probability of frequent relations in 2010 than those who stayed out of poverty.

If we move down Table  3 , to the three bottom lines, the change and comparison groups are now different. The comparison group is the “constantly poor” (1–1), and the change group are “poverty leavers” (1–0). Again following the columns downwards, we can see that the change group improved their social relations in comparison with the constantly poor; and this is true whether they started out with weak social relations or not. In fact, the chance of improvement for those who started off with non-frequent social relations is the most noteworthy, being 33 % units higher for those who escaped poverty than for those who did not. In sum, Table  3 suggests that becoming poor appears to be bad for social relations whereas escaping poverty is beneficial.

Expanding the Model

The model exemplified in Table  3 is a panel model that studies change across time within the same individuals, conditioning on their initial state. It does away with time-constant effects of observed and unobserved respondent characteristics, and although this is far superior to a cross-sectional model (such as the one underlying Fig.  1 ) there are still threats to causal interpretations. It is possible (if probably unusual) that permanent characteristics may trigger a change over time in both the dependent and independent variables; or, put in another way, whether a person stays in or exits poverty may be partly caused by a variable that also predicts change in the outcome (what is sometimes referred to as a violation of the “common trend assumption”). In our case, we can for example imagine that health problems in 2000 can affect who becomes poor in 2010, at t 1 , and that the same health problems can lead to a deterioration of social relations between 2000 and 2010, so even conditioning on the social relations at t 0 will not be enough. This we handle by adding control variables, attempting to condition the comparison of poor and non-poor also on sex, age, highest level of education (in 2010), immigrant status, and health (in 2000). 11

Given the set-up of our data—with 10 years between the two data-points and with no information on the precise time ordering of poverty and social outcomes at t 1 , the model can be further improved by including change in some of the control variables. It is possible, for example, that a non-poor and married respondent in 2000 divorced before 2010, triggering both poverty and reduced social relations at the time of the interview in 2010. 12 There are two major events that in this way may bias our results, divorce/separation and unemployment (because each can lead to poverty, and possibly also affect social outcomes). We handle this by controlling for variables combining civil status and unemployment in 2000 as well as in 2010. To the extent that these factors are a consequence of becoming poor, there is a risk of biasing our estimates downwards (e.g., if becoming poor increases the risk of divorce). However, as there is no way to distinguish empirically whether control variables (divorce, unemployment) or poverty changed first we prefer to report conservative estimates. 13

Throughout, we use logistic regression to estimate our models (one model for each social outcome and poverty definition). We create a dummy variable for each of the combinations of poverty in 2000, poverty in 2010 and the social outcome in 2000, and alternate the reference category in order to get the four strategic comparisons described above. Coefficients do thus express the distance between the relevant change and comparison groups. The coefficients reported are average marginal effects (AME) for a one-unit change in the respective poverty variable (i.e. going from non-poor to poor and vice versa), which are straightforwardly interpretable as percentage unit differences and (unlike odds ratios or log odds ratios) comparable across models and outcomes (Mood 2010 ).

Regression Results

As detailed above, we use changes over time in poverty and social outcomes to estimate the effects of interest. The effect of poverty is allowed to be heterogeneous, and is assessed through four comparisons of the social outcome in 2010 (Y 1 ):

  • Those entering poverty relative to those in constant non-poverty (P 01  = 0,1 vs. P 01  = 0,0) when both have favourable social outcomes at t 0 (Y 0  = 1)
  • Those exiting poverty relative to those in constant poverty (P 01  = 1,0 vs. P 01  = 1,1) when both have favourable social outcomes at t 0 (Y 0  = 1)
  • Those entering poverty relative to those in constant non-poverty (P 01  = 0,1 vs. P 01  = 0,0) when both have non-favourable social outcomes at t 0 (Y 0  = 0)
  • Those exiting poverty relative to those in constant poverty (P 01  = 1,0 vs. P 01  = 1,1) when both have non-favourable social outcomes at t 0 (Y 0  = 0)

Poverty is a rare outcome, and as noted above it is particularly uncommon to enter poverty between 2000 and 2010 because of the improving macro-economic situation. Some of the social outcomes were also rare in 2000. This unfortunately means that in some comparisons we have cell frequencies that are prohibitively small, and we have chosen to exclude all comparisons involving cells where N < 20.

The regression results are displayed in Table  4 . To understand how the estimates come to be, consider the four in the upper left part of the Table (0.330, 0.138, −0.175 and −0.065), reflecting the effect of poverty, measured as economic deprivation, on the probability of having frequent social relations. Because these estimates are all derived from a regression without any controls, they are identical (apart from using three decimal places) to the percentage comparisons in Table  3 (0.33, 0.14, −0.17, −0.07), and can be straightforwardly interpreted as average differences in the probability of the outcome in question. From Table  4 it is clear that the three first differences are all statistically significant, whereas the estimate −0.07 is not (primarily because those who entered poverty in 2010 and had infrequent social relations in 2000 is a small group, N = 25).

Table 4

Average marginal effects (from logistic regression) of five types of poverty (1–5) on four social outcomes (A-D) comparing those with different poverty statuses in 2000 and 2010 and conditioning on the starting value of the social outcome (in 2000)

Economically deprived (1)Absolute poor (2)Deprived and abs. poor (3)Long-term poor (4)Relative poor (5)
No controlsControlsNo controlsControlsNo controlsControlsNo controlsControlsNo controlsControls
P11 versus P10, Y0 = negative 0.172 0.291 0.1340.0820.130
(0.000)(0.029)(0.000)(0.114)(0.000)(0.052)(0.008)(0.251)(0.479)(0.240)
P11 versus P10, Y0 = positive 0.0500.035−0.048 0.0650.0260.034
(0.002)−0.048−0.005(0.260)(0.676)(0.374)(0.003)(0.225)(0.546)(0.455)
P00 versus P01, Y0 = positive−0.070−0.0910.013−0.013
(0.000)(0.002)(0.009)(0.084)(0.001)(0.012)(0.012)(0.082)(0.583)(0.645)
P00 versus P01, Y0 = negative−0.065−0.0480.1160.042
(0.536)(0.635)(0.241)(0.668)
P11 versus P10, Y0 = negative 0.1020.2000.1020.2000.108
(0.030)(0.190)(0.079)(0.177)(0.133)(0.235)
P11 versus P10, Y0 = positive0.0300.002 0.0180.056−0.006 0.0210.0420.052
(0.248)(0.928)−0.039(0.532)(0.356)(0.882)(0.039)(0.524)(0.147)(0.105)
P00 versus P01, Y0 = positive−0.045−0.063−0.045
(0.023)(0.050)(0.050)(0.089)(0.025)(0.037)(0.112)(0.176)(0.002)(0.022)
P00 versus P01, Y0 = negative
P11 versus P10, Y0 = negative 0.0470.032
(0.001)(0.006)(0.003)(0.038)(0.391)(0.616)(0.005)(0.041)(0.015)−0.034
P11 versus P10, Y0 = positive
P00 versus P01, Y0 = negative−0.066−0.077−0.058−0.044−0.034−0.044−0.036
(0.008)(0.023)(0.029)(0.090)(0.140)(0.343)(0.374)(0.516)(0.113)(0.222)
P00 versus P01, Y0 = positive−0.0508−0.0230.1110.104−0.121−0.121
(0.589)(0.815)(0.301)(0.334)(0.113)(0.115)
P11 versus P10, Y0 = negative 0.0910.0480.0290.0930.1080.0890.0830.0260.012
(0.032)(0.091)(0.408)(0.680)(0.155)(0.188)(0.164)(0.295)(0.636)(0.845)
P11 versus P10, Y0 = positive0.0680.047 0.1880.1490.151−0.017−0.067
(0.372)(0.543)(0.041)(0.055)(0.157)(0.167)(0.843)(0.396)
P00 versus P01, Y0 = negative−0.078−0.0390.0090.029
(0.126)(0.493)(0.000)(0.001)(0.008)(0.042)(0.003)(0.017)(0.853)(0.570)
P00 versus P01, Y0 = positive−0.125−0.0080.032−0.080−0.056−0.0080.054−0.0390.002
(0.035)(0.107)(0.920)(0.682)(0.478)(0.625)(0.943)(0.611)(0.453)(0.973)

Right columns control for sex, education, age, immigrant status, health in 2000, civil status change between 2000 and 2010, and unemployment change between 2000 and 2010. P values in parentheses. Excluded estimates involve variable categories with N < 20. Shaded cells are in hypothesized direction, bold estimates are statistically significant ( P  < 0.05). N in regressions: 1A: 3075; 1B: 3073; 1C: 3075; 1D: 3069; 2A: 3144; 2B: 3137; 2C: 3144; 2D: 3130; 3A: 3074, 3B: 3072; 3C: 3074; 3D: 3068; 4A: 2995; 4B: 2988; 4C: 2995; 4D: 2981; 5A: 3128; 5B: 3121; 5C: 3128; 5D: 3114

In the column to the right, we can see what difference the controls make: the estimates are reduced, but not substantially so, and the three first differences are still statistically significant.

The estimates for each social outcome, reflecting the four comparisons described above, support the hypothesis of poverty affecting social relations negatively (note that the signs of the estimates should differ in order to do so, the upper two being positive as they reflect an effect of the exit from poverty, and the lower two being negative as they reflect an effect of entering poverty). We have indicated support for the hypothesis in Table  4 by shading the estimates and standard errors for estimates that go in the predicted direction.

Following the first two columns down, we can see that there is mostly support for the hypothesis of a negative effect of poverty, but when controlling for other variables, the effects on social support are not impressive. In fact, if we concentrate on each social outcome (i.e., row-wise), one conclusion is that, when controlling for confounders, there are rather small effects of poverty on the probability of having access to social support. The opposite is true for political participation, where the consistency in the estimated effects of poverty is striking.

If we instead follow the columns, we ask whether any of the definitions of poverty is a better predictor of social outcomes than the others. The measure of economic deprivation appears to be the most stable one, followed by absolute poverty and the combined deprivation/absolute poverty variable. 14 The relative poverty measure is less able to predict social outcomes: in many instances it even has the non-expected sign. Interestingly, long-term poverty (as measured here) does not appear to have more severe negative consequences than absolute poverty in general.

Because some of our comparison groups are small, it is difficult to get high precision in the estimates, efficiency being a concern particularly in view of the set of control variables in Table  4 . Only 14 out of 62 estimates in models with controls are significant and in the right direction. Nonetheless, with 52 out of 62 estimates in these models having the expected sign, we believe that the hypothesis of a negative effect of poverty on social outcomes receives quite strong support.

Although control variables are not shown in the table, one thing should be noted about them: The reduction of coefficients when including control variables is almost exclusively driven by changes in civil status. 15 The time constant characteristics that are included are cross-sectionally related to both poverty and social outcomes, but they have only minor impacts on the estimated effects of poverty. This suggests that the conditioning on prior values of the dependent and independent variables eliminates much time invariant heterogeneity, which increases the credibility of estimates.

Conclusions

We set out to test a fundamental, but rarely questioned assumption in dominating definitions of poverty: whether shortage of economic resources has negative consequences for social relations and participation. By using longitudinal data from the Swedish Level-of-living Surveys 2000 and 2010, including repeated measures of poverty (according to several commonly used definitions) and four social outcome variables, we are able to come further than previous studies in estimating the relation between poverty and social outcomes: Our main conclusion is that there appears to be a causal relation between them.

Panel models suggest that falling into poverty increases the risk of weakening social relations and decreasing (civic and political) participation. Climbing out of poverty tends to have the opposite effects, a result that strengthens the interpretation of causality. The sample is too small to estimate the effect sizes with any precision, yet they appear to be substantial, with statistically significant estimates ranging between 5 and 21 % units.

While these findings are disquieting insofar as poverty goes, our results also suggest two more positive results. First, the negative effects of poverty appear to be reversible: once the private economy recovers, social outcomes improve. Secondly, the negative consequences are less for the closest social relations, whether there is someone there in cases of need (sickness, personal problems, etc.). This is in line with an interpretation of such close relations being unconditional: our nearest and dearest tend to hang on to us also in times of financial troubles, which may bolster risks for social isolation and psychological ill-being,

Our finding of negative effects of poverty on civic and political participation relates to the fears of a “downward spiral of social exclusion”, as there is a risk that the loss of less intimate social relations shrinks social networks and decreases the available social capital in terms of contacts that can be important for outcomes such as finding a job (e.g., Lin 2001 ; Granovetter 1974 ). However, Gallie et al. ( 2003 ) found no evidence for any strong impact of social isolation on unemployment, suggesting that the negative effects on social outcomes that we observe are unlikely to lead to self-reinforcement of poverty. Nevertheless, social relations are of course important outcomes in their own right, so if they are negatively affected by poverty it matters regardless of whether social relations in turn are important for other outcomes. Effects on political and civic participation are also relevant in themselves beyond individuals’ wellbeing, as they suggest a potentially democratic problem where poor have less of a voice and less influence on society than others.

Our results show the merits of our approach, to study the relation between poverty and social outcomes longitudinally. The fact that the poor have worse social relations and lower participation is partly because of selection. This may be because the socially isolated, or those with a weaker social network, more easily fall into poverty; or it can be because of a common denominator, such as poor health or social problems. But once we have stripped the analysis of such selection effects, we also find what is likely to be a causal relation between poverty and social relations. However, this effect of poverty on social outcomes, in turn, varies between different definitions of poverty. Here it appears that economic deprivation, primarily indicated by the ability of raising money with short notice, is the strongest predictor of social outcomes. Income poverty, whether in absolute or (particularly) relative terms, are weaker predictors of social outcomes, which is interesting as they are the two most common indicators of poverty in existing research.

Even if we are fortunate to have panel data at our disposal, there are limitations in our analyses that render our conclusions tentative. One is that we do not have a random allocation to the comparison groups at t 0 ; another that there is a 10-year span between the waves that we analyze, and both poverty and social outcomes may vary across this time-span. We have been able to address these problems by conditioning on the outcome at t 0 and by controlling for confounders, but in order to perform more rigorous tests future research would benefit from data with a more detailed temporal structure, and preferably with an experimental or at least quasi-experimental design.

Finally, our analyses concern Sweden, and given the position as an active welfare state with a low degree of inequality and low poverty rates, one can ask whether the results are valid also for other comparable countries. While both the level of poverty and the pattern of social relations differ between countries (for policy or cultural reasons), we believe that the mechanisms linking poverty and social outcomes are of a quite general kind, especially as the “costs for social participation” can be expected to be relative to the general wealth of a country—however, until comparative longitudinal data become available, this must remain a hypothesis for future research.

1 http://www.sofi.su.se/english/2.17851/research/three-research-departments/lnu-level-of-living .

2 We have tested various alternative codings and the overall pattern of results in terms of e.g., direction of effects and differences across poverty definitions are similar, but more difficult to present in an accessible way.

3 Our deprivation questions are however designed to reduce the impact of subjectivity by asking, e.g., about getting a specified sum within a specified time (see below).

4 In the equivalence scale, the first adult gets a weight of one, the second of 0.6, and each child gets a weight of 0.5.

5 We have also tried using single indicators (either a/b or i/ii) without detecting any meaningful difference between them. One would perhaps have assumed that poverty would be more consequential for having others over to one’s own place, but the absence of support for this can perhaps be understood in light of the strong social norm of reciprocity in social relations.

6 We have refrained from using information on voting and membership in trade unions and political parties, because these indicators do not capture the active, social nature of civic engagement to the same extent as participation in meetings and the holding of positions.

7 We have also estimated models with a more extensive health variable, a s ymptom index , which sums responses to 47 questions about self-reported health symptoms. However, this variable has virtually zero effects once global self-rated health is controlled, and does not lead to any substantive differences in other estimates. Adding the global health measure and the symptom index as TVC had no effect either.

8 Using the other indicators of poverty yields very similar results, although for some of those the difference between poor and non-poor is smaller.

9 We call these comparison groups ”never poor” and ”constantly poor” for expository purposes, although their poverty status pertains only to the years 2000 and 2010, i.e., without information on the years in between.

10 With this design we allow different effects of poverty on improvement versus deterioration of the social outcome. We have also estimated models with a lagged dependent variable, which constrains the effects of poverty changes to be of the same size for deterioration as for improvement of the social outcome. Conclusions from that analysis are roughly a weighted average of the estimates for deterioration and improvement that we report. As our analyses suggest that effects of poverty differ in size depending on the value of the lagged dependent variable (the social outcome) our current specification gives a more adequate representation of the process.

11 We have also tested models with a wider range of controls for, e.g., economic and social background (i.e. characteristics of the respondent’s parents), geography, detailed family type and a more detailed health variable, but none of these had any impact on the estimated poverty effects.

12 It is also possible that we register reverse causality, namely if worsening social outcomes that occur after t 0 lead to poverty at t 1 . This situation is almost inevitable when using panel data with no clear temporal ordering of events occurring between waves. However, reverse causality strikes us, in this case, as theoretically implausible.

13 We have also estimated models controlling for changes in health, which did not change the results.

14 If respondents’ judgments of the deprivation questions (access to cash margin and ability to pay rent, food, bills etc.) change due to non-economic factors that are related to changes in social relations, the better predictive capacity of the deprivation measure may be caused by a larger bias in this measure than in the (register-based) income measures.

15 As mentioned above, this variable may to some extent be endogenous (i.e., a mediator of the poverty effect rather than a confounder), in which case we get a downward bias of estimates.

Contributor Information

Carina Mood, Phone: +44-8-402 12 22, Email: [email protected] .

Jan O. Jonsson, Phone: +44 1865 278513, Email: [email protected] .

  • Atkinson AB, Cantillon B, Marlier E, Nolan B. Social indicators: The EU and social inclusion. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2002. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Attree P. The social costs of child poverty: A systematic review of the qualitative evidence. Children and Society. 2006; 20 :54–66. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bane MJ, Ellwood DT. Slipping into and out of Poverty: The Dynamics of Spells. Journal of Human Resources. 1986; 21 :1–23. doi: 10.2307/145955. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Barnes M, Heady C, Middleton S, Millar J, Papadopoulos F, Room G, Tsakloglou P. Poverty and social exclusion in Europe. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar; 2002. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Böhnke P. Are the poor socially integrated? The link between poverty and social support in different welfare regimes. Journal of European Social Policy. 2008; 18 :133–150. doi: 10.1177/0958928707087590. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bradshaw J, Finch N. Overlaps in dimensions of poverty. Journal of Social Policy. 2003; 32 :513–525. doi: 10.1017/S004727940300713X. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Callan T, Nolan B, Whelan CT. Resources, deprivation, and the measurement of poverty. Journal of Social Policy. 1993; 22 :141–172. doi: 10.1017/S0047279400019280. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Corak M. Principles and practicalities for measuring child poverty in the rich countries. International Social Security Review. 2006; 59 :3–36. doi: 10.1111/j.1468-246X.2006.00237.x. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Dahl E, Flotten T, Lorentzen T. Poverty dynamics and social exclusion: An analysis of Norwegian panel data. Journal of Social Policy. 2008; 37 :231–249. doi: 10.1017/S0047279407001729. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Duncan GJ, Gustafsson B, Hauser R, Schmauss G, Messinger H, Muffels R, Nolan B, Ray J-C. Poverty dynamics in eight countries. Journal of Population Economics. 1993; 6 :215–234. doi: 10.1007/BF00163068. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Duncan GJ, Rodgers W. Has children’s poverty become more persistent? American Sociological Review. 1991; 56 :538–550. doi: 10.2307/2096273. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Galbraith J. The affluent society. Boston: Houghton-Mifflin; 1958. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Gallie D, Paugam S, Jacobs S. Unemployment, poverty and social isolation: Is there a vicious cycle of social exclusion? European Societies. 2003; 5 :1–32. doi: 10.1080/1461669032000057668. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Gordon D, Adelman L, Ashworth K, Bradshaw J, Levitas R, Middleton S, Pantazis C, Patsios D, Payne S, Townsend P, Williams J. Poverty and social exclusion in Britain. York: Joseph Rowntree Foundation; 2000. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Gore C. Introduction: Markets, citizenship and social exclusion. In: Rodgers G, Gore C, Figueiredo JB, editors. Social exclusion: Rhetoric, reality, responses. Geneva: International Labour Organization; 1995. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Granovetter, M. S. (1974). Getting a job. A study of contacts and careers . Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
  • Halleröd B. The truly poor: Direct and indirect measurement of consensual poverty in Sweden. Journal of European Social Policy. 1995; 5 :111–129. doi: 10.1177/095892879500500203. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Hills J, Le Grand J, Piachaud D. Understanding social exclusion. Oxford: OUP; 2002. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Jansson, K. (2000). Inkomstfördelningen under 1990-talet. In Välfärd och försörjning 2000, pp. 15–60. SOU 2000:40.
  • Jonsson, J. O., Mood, C., & Bihagen, E. (2010). Fattigdomens förändring, utbredning och dynamik, Chapter 3. In Social Rapport 2010 . Stockholm: Socialstyrelsen.
  • Jonsson, J. O., & Östberg, V. (2004). Resurser och levnadsförhållanden bland ekonomiskt utsatta 10-18-åringar: Analys av Barn-LNU och Barn-ULF. pp. 203–55 in Ekonomiskt utsatta barn, Socialdepartementet, Ds. 2004:41. Stockholm: Fritzes.
  • Levitas R. The concept and measurement of social exclusion. In: Pantazis C, Gordon D, Levitas R, editors. Poverty and social exclusion in Britain. Bristol: Policy Press; 2006. pp. 123–162. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Lin, N. (2001). Social capital. A theory of social structure and action . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.  
  • Mack J, Lansley S. Poor Britain. London: Allen & Unwin Ltd; 1985. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Mood C. Logistic regression: Why we cannot do what we think we can do and what we can do about it. European Sociological Review. 2010; 26 :67–82. doi: 10.1093/esr/jcp006. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Nolan B, Whelan CT. Poverty and deprivation in Europe. New York: Oxford University Press; 2011. [ Google Scholar ]
  • OECD . Growing unequal? Income distribution and poverty in OECD countries. Paris: OECD Publishing; 2008. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Paugam S. The spiral of precariousness: A multidimensional approach to the process of social disqualification in France. In: Room G, editor. Beyond the threshold: The measurement and analysis of social exclusion. Bristol: Policy Press; 1995. pp. 47–79. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ridge T, Millar J. Following families: Working lone-mother families and their children. Social Policy & Administration. 2011; 45 :85–97. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9515.2010.00755.x. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ringen S. Direct and indirect measures of poverty. Journal of Social Policy. 1988; 17 :351–365. doi: 10.1017/S0047279400016858. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Rodgers G, Gore C, Figueiredo JB, editors. Social exclusion: Rhetoric, reality, responses. Geneva: International Labour Organization; 1995. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Rodgers JR, Rodgers JL. Chronic poverty in the United States. Journal of Human Resources. 1993; 28 :25–54. doi: 10.2307/146087. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Room G, editor. Beyond the threshold: The measurement and analysis of social exclusion. Bristol: Policy Press; 1995. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Sen A. Poor, relatively speaking. Oxford Economic Papers. 1983; 35 :153–169. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Smith, A. (1776). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations (republished by R. H. Campbell and A. S. Skinner (Eds.). Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1976).
  • Townsend P. Poverty in the United Kingdom. Harmondsworth: Penguin; 1979. [ Google Scholar ]
  • van den Bosch K. Identifying the poor: Using subjective and consensual measures. Aldershot: Ashgate; 2001. [ Google Scholar ]
  • United Nations. (1995). United nations world summit (Copenhagen) for social development. programme of action , Chapter 2. New York: United Nations.
  • UNICEF. (2012). Measuring child poverty. New league tables of child poverty in the world’s rich countries. In Innocenti Report Card 10 . Florence: UNICEF Innocenti Research Centre.
  • Veblen T. The theory of the leisure class. New York: McMillan; 1899. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Whelan CT, Layte R, Maitre B. Persistent income poverty and deprivation in the European Union: An analysis of the first three waves of the European community household panel. Journal of Social Policy. 2003; 32 :1–18. doi: 10.1017/S0047279402006864. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]

Pardon Our Interruption

As you were browsing something about your browser made us think you were a bot. There are a few reasons this might happen:

  • You've disabled JavaScript in your web browser.
  • You're a power user moving through this website with super-human speed.
  • You've disabled cookies in your web browser.
  • A third-party browser plugin, such as Ghostery or NoScript, is preventing JavaScript from running. Additional information is available in this support article .

To regain access, please make sure that cookies and JavaScript are enabled before reloading the page.

research paper on poverty and crime

Tuesday, September 17, 2024

Poverty, crime the thorns in the tourist paradise that is SA

Statistics show that South Africa is experiencing growing popularity as a tourist destination; unfortunately, crime is also increasing, says the writer. Picture: Armand Hough/Independent Newspapes Archive

Statistics show that South Africa is experiencing growing popularity as a tourist destination; unfortunately, crime is also increasing, says the writer. Picture: Armand Hough/Independent Newspapes Archive

Published 16h ago

FREDDIE HINEY

On exterior, South Africa exudes beauty; its interior, however, includes integral cracks, harming a promising nation.

Plagued by crime, unemployment and treacherous living conditions, there’s plenty to blame regarding the country’s in-house demolition –but that hasn’t stopped a record number of tourists from visiting.

The South African Government News Agency says 8.5 million international tourists entered the country last year, nearly 50% higher than 2022’s count. A further 6.4 million visitors entered from other African countries, increasing the total to 14.9 million.

The figure is forecast to rise this year. It’s hard to argue that the recent pandemic doesn’t elevate the statistics, as 2022 marked the first year free from isolation, a time when many, scarred from recent events, weren’t willing to travel. But comparing it to the pre-Covid days, namely 2018, which entailed 10.37 million tourists, it’s clear our nation is experiencing growing popularity (and fast).

A similar pattern applies to crime.

After 2022/23, the country’s per capita murder rate was the highest in 20 years at 45 per 100 000 – a 50% jump from a decade ago. On average, according to the SAPS, 84 people are murdered every day.

An underlying yin and yang tone reverberates through the country – a balance between its charm and its challenges, between what there is to love and what there is to hate.

Whether you live in Cape Town, Johannesburg or the Garden Route, from urban to rural, the presence of foreigners was felt during the summer months, for better or worse. Suddenly, a drive to work, which lasted 20 minutes, took 40.

But, for the sake of independent businesses, street sellers and the overall economy, it’s worth it.

The phrase “seasonal” hits true to many entrepreneurs and businesses around South Africa – often banking it in the summer and hibernating in the winter, recording a fraction of the sales than they experienced during the warmer months.

Without waves of tourists, many industries would perish, and our weakened economy would be comparable to Zimbabwe and Zambia.

Unfortunately, there’s nothing seasonal about our crime statistics; all year round, it continues, from gender-based violence to robbery and murder.

Along with being labelled the “Rape Capital of the World” by the international criminal police organisation, Interpol, South Africa experienced approximately 238 000 home robberies between March 2022 and March last year. That’s 652 a day.

Combine this with the fact that, on average, 65 vehicles are stolen every day – 5 937 hijackings occurred from October to December last year – and it’s easy to identify that this beautiful country has an ugly truth: crime is everywhere.

Many blame unemployment and a lack of social housing; around 19.7 million citizens are without jobs, and unlike First World countries such as England and Australia, which provide monthly unemployment grants of around R8 500, South Africans receive R350 (95.88% less).

How can anyone support themselves, let alone a family, on R87.50 a week? They can’t. And here lies the smoking gun – the definitive proof of a failing system that perpetuates poverty and drives desperate people toward crime.

Then there’s the realisation that in the 21st century – a wannabe utopian time where cars are becoming driverless (some even fly), and houses are being built by 3D printers – more than 11.6 million South Africans, nearly 20% of the population, live in townships, confined by ageing roof sheets held down by rocks that counteract neither the heat nor the cold.

And you often ask yourself, ‘How can people live like this?’ They can’t, but it’s all they have.

However, like a Hollywood love story, among the chaos, there’s promise. Cape Town, a contemporary city renowned for its art, culture and stunning scenery – the same attractions as New York, Tokyo and London – resembles some of the world’s greatest cities.

Yes, Paris might have the Eiffel Tower and Barcelona boasts the Gothic Quarter, but have you seen Table Mountain? What about Blyde River Canyon or Chapman’s Peak at sunset?

Then you can attest that we’ve got what many countries dream of: an abundance of natural wonder.

Unique and vibrant, the Mother City intertwines among seemingly endless mountain ranges where vineyards thrive and the ocean is never far away, a dreamland for visitors.

Johannesburg is also experiencing a much-needed revitalisation. Brimming with its own edgy and vibrant creativity, there’s a heady mix of internationally acclaimed jazz and street music, opulent restaurants, world-renowned galleries and a living recent history of rebellion and reconciliation that transfixed the world.

Such areas include the Maboneng Precinct, a once-dilapidated neighbourhood that has been uplifted into a high-end district of galleries, eateries and shops, and Victoria Yards, a former steam laundry warehouse used to wash hospital sheets now home to artisans, artists and feel-good philanthropy.

Many argue that transforming rundown, crime-ridden precincts into boutique centres benefit only the rich, but does it? Yes, the rich become richer (an inevitable outcome in today’s world), but this also means more jobs. And as these areas become populated, the likelihood of crime reduces, rejuvenating once-lonely, vulnerable streets into lively social hubs filled with laughter, smiles and joy.

The effect is evident during Cape Town’s First Thursdays, when attendees, usually in the thousands, freely explore the CBD at night, feeling secure with the presence of people around them.

Within our cities are a plethora of establishments that would belong on any high street in the world, whether it’s in London, New York or Madrid; however, they record a fraction of the crimes we do.

I’m not saying the capital cities are without problems; knife attacks are rising in London, but the numbers don’t lie; we’ve got bigger fish to fry.

Widely renowned as a sleeping giant, Africa has long been a hot spot for international investment – out of the 20 fastest-growing economies in the world, nine are here. That suggests an influx in money, but it hasn’t resulted in a crackdown on crime, which, again, makes you think: ‘Where are these billions of rand going?’ The Eastern Cape’s roads certainly aren’t getting any better.

Yet, to our dismay, tens of millions of tourists annually flood South Africa’s streets, beaches and safaris. Can you blame them? Absolutely not.

Along with world-class First World delights, it’s littered with postcard-worthy settings, from Table Mountain and the Drakensberg to the Orange River and Tsitsikamma National Park.

It’s a country the Big Five happily call home and white sand beaches separate promenades from translucent, turquoise water reminiscent of the Caribbean. It’s a place where mountain ranges traverse mesmerising terrain, hosting waterfalls, wildlife, forests and unfathomable views. There’s nowhere else like it – but the crime must stop.

* Hiney has written for global publications and is the co-author of “The NFT Yearbook”, set to be published later this year.

Related Topics:

COMMENTS

  1. The Relationship Between Poverty and Crime:

    Crime is a complicated issue, and other variables like education, healthcare, and housing have to be taken into consideration. The results indicate that there is a relationship between certain types of crime and poverty, and that income inequality is significant to all types of crime. JEL Classification: I32, A13.

  2. Urban Poverty and Neighborhood Effects on Crime: Incorporating Spatial

    We advance the case that, in understanding the impact of neighborhoods and poverty on crime, sociological and criminological research would benefit from expanding the analytical focus from residential neighborhoods to the network of neighborhoods individuals are exposed to during their daily routine activities. This perspective is supported by ...

  3. Dynamic linkages between poverty, inequality, crime, and social

    The study examines the relationship between growth-inequality-poverty (GIP) triangle and crime rate under the premises of inverted U-shaped Kuznets curve and pro-poor growth scenario in a panel of 16 diversified countries, over a period of 1990-2014. The study employed panel Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) estimator for robust inferences. The results show that there is (i) no/flat ...

  4. Why do inequality and deprivation produce high crime and low trust

    In line with compositional explanations, across US counties, the association between inequality and rate of property crime is fully mediated by the prevalence of poverty, which is higher in more ...

  5. (PDF) The dynamics of poverty and crime

    Each criminal costs society about $5,700 per year due to lost productivity. (Kelly, 2000), and a total of $24 billion in goods is lost in the US each year. to property crime (US Dept. of Justice ...

  6. 27 Poverty and Crime

    The evidence we have reviewed suggests a set of core findings that characterize the relationship between poverty and crime at the level of the individual and the community. First, poverty is strongly associated with crime at both levels of analysis. In the rational choice, or economic model, of crime, the individual-level relationship between ...

  7. The poverty-crime nexus revisited: absolute poverty, relative poverty

    Furthermore, researchers who have connected nations' crime rates to their poverty levels have tended to use infant mortality rates (a health outcome variable) as a proxy for poverty. This article presents findings from the first study of cross-national crime differences to use measures of "absolute" poverty (% with purchasing power under ...

  8. Income inequality, poverty and crime across nations

    Abstract. We examine the relationship between income inequality, poverty, and different types of crime. Our results are consistent with recent research in showing that inequality is unrelated to homicide rates when poverty is controlled. In our multi-level analyses of the International Crime Victimization Survey we find that inequality is ...

  9. Poverty, Income Inequality, and Violent Crime: A Meta-Analysis of

    The research presented here applies the procedures of meta-analysis to 34 aggregate data studies reporting on violent crime, poverty, and income inequality. These studies reported a total of 76 zero-order correlation coefficients for all measures of violent crime with either poverty or income inequality. Of the 76 coefficients, all but 2, or 97 ...

  10. The poverty-crime nexus revisited: absolute poverty, relative poverty

    This article presents findings from the first study of cross-national crime differences to use measures of "absolute" poverty (% with purchasing power under $1.90 per day at 2011 prices) and ...

  11. Does poverty lead to crime? Evidence from the United States of America

    The purpose of this paper is to find out the impact of poverty on crime in the USA.,Using time series data of USA over the period from 1965 to 2016, this study applies autoregressive distributed lag approach to identify the effect of poverty on crime.,The outcomes confirm a positive co-integrating relationship between poverty and property crime.

  12. (PDF) Poverty, Inequality and the Social Causes of Crime: A Study

    Ukoji and Okolie (2016) [30] found that the majority of offenders engage in criminal activity for a variety of reasons, such as drug use, lack of job, pressure to close the wealth-poverty gap ...

  13. Poverty as a Harbinger of Crime

    Ucha (2010) avers that poverty triggered by lack of employment is a catalyst for high rates of crime and violence particularly among many unemployed youths. Adebayo (2013) believes that chronic and pervasive unemployment levels push people into criminal activities out of sheer frustration and desperation.

  14. Is poverty the mother of crime? Evidence from homicide rates in China

    Abstract. Income inequality is blamed for being the main driver of violent crime by the majority of the literature. However, earlier work on the topic largely neglects the role of poverty and income levels as opposed to income inequality. The current paper uses all court verdicts for homicide cases in China between 2014 and 2016, as well as ...

  15. PDF Poverty and Crime Review

    ous violent crime'. Lee's (2000) study of black and white homicide over 3 years found that disadvantage was more important than race in exp. ining homicide rates. Pridemore's review found that 'poverty is the most consistent predictor of area homicide rates in the US empirical l.

  16. PDF CRIME, URBAN POVERTY, AND SOCIAL SCIENCE

    Cloth, $25.95. In recent years, sociologists have conducted enormously important research on the intersection of urban poverty, crime, and the racial divide. Quantitative stratification sociologist Bruce Western provides a meticulous tracing of the emergence of mass incarceration, tracking its steady development and identifying how and why ...

  17. Crime and Poverty: A Search-Theoretic Approach

    pioneered by Becker (1968) and Ehrlich (1973), largely focuses on the determinants of malfeasant. behavior and attempts to circumscribe the efficacy of punishment as a deterrent. Important recent. exceptions include Imrohoroglu et al. (2000, 2004) who construct general (competitive) equilibrium models of crime.

  18. The Social Consequences of Poverty: An Empirical Test on Longitudinal

    Abstract. Poverty is commonly defined as a lack of economic resources that has negative social consequences, but surprisingly little is known about the importance of economic hardship for social outcomes. This article offers an empirical investigation into this issue. We apply panel data methods on longitudinal data from the Swedish Level-of ...

  19. (PDF) Introduction: Crime and poverty nexus

    1. Introduction: Urban Crime and Pove rty Nexus. George Owusu 1. Abstract. A key issue that has attracted the attention of criminologists and others in the field of crime studies. is the extent to ...

  20. PDF Institute for Research on Poverty

    In this paper, we review a range of rigorous research studies that estimate the average statistical. relationships between children growing up in poverty and their earnings, propensity to commit crime, and. quality of health later in life. We also review estimates of the costs that crime and poor health per person.

  21. Full article: Defining the characteristics of poverty and their

    1. Introduction. Poverty "is one of the defining challenges of the 21st Century facing the world" (Gweshengwe et al., Citation 2020, p. 1).In 2019, about 1.3 billion people in 101 countries were living in poverty (United Nations Development Programme and Oxford Poverty and Human Development Initiative, Citation 2019).For this reason, the 2030 Global Agenda for Sustainable Development Goals ...

  22. Full article: Growing up in single-parent families and the criminal

    The assessment of the data showed that 34 studies reported a statistically significant positive relation between single-parent families and crime (i.e. growing up in a single-parent family is related to a higher level of crime by adolescents), while 14 studies showed no statistically significant relation.

  23. THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN POVERTY AND CRIME

    Abstract. One of the major problems facing many countries is poverty. The factor of poverty among the causes of crime. increases its importance from day to day. Crime can be defined as a violat ...

  24. Understanding Poverty: Causes, Impacts, and Solutions

    SOCI 201 During this course, you are required to compose an original 8-page research paper that addresses a social problem and investigates possible solutions for the problem. The paper should include at least 5 scholarly sources and should be formatted in APA style. Throughout the course, you will submit various parts of the paper. Each part is explained in detail in the items below.

  25. Poverty, crime the thorns in the tourist paradise that is SA

    A similar pattern applies to crime. After 2022/23, the country's per capita murder rate was the highest in 20 years at 45 per 100 000 - a 50% jump from a decade ago.