We use cookies to enhance our website for you. Proceed if you agree to this policy or learn more about it.

  • Essay Database >
  • Essay Examples >
  • Essays Topics >
  • Essay on Social Issues

United States Welfare System Argumentative Essay Examples

Type of paper: Argumentative Essay

Topic: Social Issues , Finance , Family , Poverty , Welfare , White Collar Crime , System , Support

Published: 02/05/2020

ORDER PAPER LIKE THIS

The welfare system was put in place to ensure that support is offered to the poverty stricken families, underprivileged individuals and other various dependant persons. The United States economy is considered to being among the world strongest economies, therefore, the living standards also become relatively high and ultimately harder for some individuals to survive without financial support from the government. This program has been running since the great depression of 1935 and has continued to provide support for the survival of underprivileged families (Cook and Edith 14). However, this same welfare system that was once meant to provide support and alleviate poverty from our society has been highly abused and misused by the same people it is meant to offer aid to. In this paper, I will discuss the pros and Cons of this system, how it is being misused, and the reforms in our legal system that are required to be conducted so as to ensure that the intended purpose of this welfare program has been achieved. The US welfare system consists of both pros and Cons in equal measure. The most significant argument in favor of the system is that this program assists children who apparently have nothing to do to influence their family’s financial situation and therefore it is logical to have their basic needs met and not to punish them because of their parents shortcomings. In addition, the system has helped many people in the US get back onto their feet and eventually become self sufficient. It is also argued that this program has helped many people who do not have access to employer-provided medical insurance gain and acquire health care. Conversely, there are also numerous Cons to this system. One of the major setbacks this program faces is the issue regarding fraud. Although welfare fraud is regarded as a criminal activity, many people still cheat the system regularly and are never caught. This is because this system probably lacks enough employees who can thoroughly investigate the many applications for assistance. Another disadvantage occurring to this system is that it tends to create unnecessary dependence. It promotes laziness since most of your needs are met by the state. In fact, some individuals find it more profitable not to work than to start working and loosing the Welfare benefits. Lastly, the welfare system appears to discourage marriages. Though the ultimate goal of this public assistance program is to foster the development of a stable two-parent family, its current administrative stand proves otherwise. When a couple gets married, their total income is usually enough to disqualify them from being given the child care assistance by the state, there making some opportunistic individuals refraining from marriage institutions.

Works cited

Cook, Fay L, and Edith J. Barrett. Support for the American Welfare State: The Views of Congress and the Public. New York: Columbia University Press, 2007. Print.

double-banner

Cite this page

Share with friends using:

Removal Request

Removal Request

Finished papers: 856

This paper is created by writer with

ID 257621392

If you want your paper to be:

Well-researched, fact-checked, and accurate

Original, fresh, based on current data

Eloquently written and immaculately formatted

275 words = 1 page double-spaced

submit your paper

Get your papers done by pros!

Other Pages

Free legal issues and components of essay sample, good literature review about immunohistochemistry in gynecologic malignancies, eh 101 essay sample, essay on q4 which two major skills in your point of view is important to be a leader, free geo design essay sample, good civil war and reconstruction another american revolution essay example, free argumentative essay on the role of palliative medical care in geriatrics, sample literature review on complete name of the student, good example of case study on the implications of individual freedom and organizational control to the future organization, cat in the rain essay sample, example of essay on women and literature, free empires essay example, the palliative care approach in australia a deeper understanding essay sample, example of utilitarianism an argument paper essay, a comparison analysis of pieta from cologne cathedral in germany and essay examples, multi cultural virtual teams research papers example, good essay on cognitive psychology, critical thinking on relation of the article to the topic, william barnes essays, darkness visible essays, w h davies essays, dream of the rood essays, collagen synthesis essays, langkawi essays, the noises essays, tom scott essays, standing firm essays, the rape of lucrece essays, port harcourt essays, corporate settings essays, two islands essays, john harris essays, transitive verb essays, descriptive analysis essays, druid essays, decedent essays, rhode island essays, barro essays, dotting essays, berkman essays, atari essays, cartridges essays, pet shops essays.

Password recovery email has been sent to [email protected]

Use your new password to log in

You are not register!

By clicking Register, you agree to our Terms of Service and that you have read our Privacy Policy .

Now you can download documents directly to your device!

Check your email! An email with your password has already been sent to you! Now you can download documents directly to your device.

or Use the QR code to Save this Paper to Your Phone

The sample is NOT original!

Short on a deadline?

Don't waste time. Get help with 11% off using code - GETWOWED

No, thanks! I'm fine with missing my deadline

The Shortcomings of a Work-Biased Welfare System

The recently passed American Rescue Plan Act has once again brought attention to the U.S. welfare system. This EB provides an overview of the welfare system — including recent changes — and assesses the system's effectiveness in achieving its goals. The brief highlights a "work bias" that is embedded in many U.S. welfare programs and has both intended and unintended effects on the system's ability to combat poverty.

All advanced economies have implemented safety net programs with the goal of ensuring that basic standards of living are met for everyone. These safety net programs — collectively known as welfare systems — strive to put floors on how low individuals' consumption and well-being can go.

While opinions differ regarding the size and nature of welfare systems, most agree that any redistribution should be accomplished as efficiently and equitably as possible. Naturally, then, changes to how transfers are determined and carried out attract the public's attention.

The U.S. welfare system includes a broad variety of means-tested programs aimed at reducing poverty by providing government-sponsored benefits to eligible individuals and families. While these programs have helped shrink poverty dramatically in the U.S., it has not been eliminated. Currently, one out of every six Americans is poor according to the U.S. government's official definition of poverty, meaning they earn less than $12,880 per year. 1

Poverty has negative consequences that are both long lasting and far reaching. There is good evidence of long-lasting harm to people — especially children — when they undergo even short, temporary stints in poverty. 2

In addition, poverty affects a larger number of people than the poor themselves, because it is often associated with drug abuse, mental health issues, involvement in the criminal justice system, increased incidence of divorce, and teen and out-of-wedlock pregnancy. Negative effects on societal well-being that surpass the damage done directly to the affected individuals are called "negative externalities" by economists. Because these externalities are generally significant, they provide additional incentives for societies to provide welfare assistance — incentives that supplement more altruistic motives such as empathy and moral obligation.

The U.S. Welfare System's Work Bias

The U.S. is rather unique among industrialized nations in the modest magnitude of its welfare system. For instance, the U.S. is the only advanced economy that does not have universal health care.

In a uniquely American way, the debate over welfare is a debate not just about fighting poverty, but also about worthiness, fairness and work ethics. Though the system has a purported goal of alleviating poverty, the goal is often framed within the context of encouraging work and disincentivizing dependence on the system itself. Thus, the focus shifts from helping the poor to helping the working poor. The U.S. welfare system's "work bias" is embodied in stringent work requirements for welfare recipients and a distinct dearth of support for able-bodied, non-elderly, jobless individuals.

The U.S. has a deep-seated tension between the concept of a safety net and the concept of self-reliance. America is considered by many to be "the land of opportunity," and the welfare system's work bias reflects the assumption that such opportunities are there for those who work hard enough.

However, the very existence of a welfare system implicitly recognizes that some may need extra help from the government, as they may not be able to gain access to such opportunities otherwise, regardless of effort. The recent economic recession — induced by the COVID-19 pandemic — has put into stark relief the consequences of connecting support to the poor to their ability to work and has challenged the previously wide consensus on a welfare system that supplements the poor's consumption conditional on them working or looking for work. This represents, perhaps, one of the most momentous shifts in the public perception of the welfare system since the mid-1990s reforms.

The Main Parts of the U.S. Welfare System

The current U.S. welfare system is rather complex. There are two main types of programs: tax credits, and benefits for poor households in the form of cash assistance or in-kind transfers.

The main benefits programs are:

  • Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF)
  • The Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (SNAP), more commonly known as food stamps
  • Subsidized housing programs, which defray housing costs
  • Medicaid and CHIP, which provide health care assistance to poor adults and children

The health care programs are by far the largest and fastest growing, accounting for well over a quarter of the federal government's budget and 5 percent of GDP. (See figure 1 below.)

How Large Are Welfare Programs?

Benefits programs are mostly in-kind in nature: They provide food, housing or medical services. The only program not entirely in-kind is TANF. About one-third of TANF's budget is spent on cash transfers, while the other two-thirds fund a diverse array of services to boost job readiness for recipients.

Most of the benefits programs have stringent work requirements and are targeted to parents, so they are typically greatly reduced or not available to poor individuals who do not work or do not have children. For example, a single mother with two children between 5 and 18 years old needs to work at least 30 hours a week to be eligible for TANF. This requirement drops to 20 hours a week if one of the children is under 5 years old. Similar work requirements are in place for housing assistance, while SNAP and Medicaid are nearly universal.

Tax credits are another large part of the welfare system. The earned income tax credit, or EITC, is an annual refund on a family's tax obligations. It is only available to those with some work earnings and is much more generous to parents than non-parents or parents whose children do not live with them. For example, in 2018, the average EITC was $3,191 for a family with children, compared with just $298 for a family without children.

EITC refunds increase with income earned for very poor households before plateauing and eventually tapering off as households continue to increase their income. This structure is both cost-effective and successful in diverting more funds to households who need them most while incentivizing work. (This is because the credit grows as income grows for the poorest households.) This flexible structure has made the EITC — and its sister program the child tax credit, or CTC — very popular.

Economists also favor tax credits because the funds from the program can be used by households to purchase goods and services as they see fit, thus enabling poor households to supplement their consumptions in an unconstrained way, while other programs such as SNAP or TANF provide funds for specific goods and services only.

The EITC and CTC have been historically very successful at lifting parents and their children above the poverty line. This is because they both encourage parents to work more — the more they earn, the more they get back in tax credits (up to a certain threshold) — and directly provide cash to families that they can spend however they like.

Indeed, if we include public transfers and tax credits when calculating the poverty rate, the after-transfer poverty rate went from 25 percent in the 1970s to approximately 15 percent currently. (See the dashed line in figure 2 below.)

How Have Poverty Rates Evolved Over Time?

Should we then interpret this figure as portraying a successful welfare system? Yes and no. It is true that the welfare system has been successful in supplementing the incomes of the poor and lifting them above the poverty line.

However, one also sees from figure 2 that the poverty rate excluding public support (solid line in figure 2) is remarkably flat over time: It currently stands at about 25 percent, as did in the 1970s. This means the ability of the poor to sustain a higher level of income independently of transfers has not changed over time.

I conclude that the welfare system has not been successful in lifting people out of poverty in a permanent way. Simplifying somewhat, we could say that it is a system that brings people out of poverty, but not up the income distribution. Despite its emphasis on self-reliance, the current structure of welfare programs has done little to foster independence and long-term income growth for poorer households. If it had, we would see the pre-transfer poverty level drop as fewer families would rely on public transfers to avoid poverty. This is unfortunately not the case.

Welfare support is relatively meager. As mentioned earlier, a single mother with two young children needs to work at least 30 hours to qualify for TANF. Even then, though, benefits are typically a small fraction of a state's median income. For example, a single mother with two children is eligible for a monthly benefit of $170 in Mississippi and a little over $1,000 in New Hampshire. The latter may seem large but is only 1.3 percent of New Hampshire's median income (and Mississippi's benefits are only 0.4 percent of that state's median income).

Although these transfers may avoid abject misery, they are hardly sufficient to purchase high-quality child care, safe and reliable housing and transportation, education and training, or health services — investments in welfare recipients' human capital that could improve their long-term earnings prospects and lower poorer families' reliance on welfare transfers to escape poverty.

The Benefits Cliff

There is also another aspect of the welfare system that hinders long-term income growth and sustained well-being for poorer families: benefits cliffs . As individuals improve their income levels, most benefit programs reduce assistance until this amount abruptly becomes zero after a pre-specified income threshold. At that point, an extra dollar earned is exceeded by the loss of benefits, resulting in net disposable income decreasing even as labor income increases.

Understandably, people facing benefits cliffs tend to turn down better-paying jobs to keep their income steady. Benefits cliffs are particularly steep for tax credits, but they are also present in all other programs.

For example, suppose that the single mother in our previous example works and qualifies for assistance (both cash and in-kind) of $1,000 per month. Let's further suppose she gets promoted to a job that pays an additional $500 per month, and this increase brings her income above the eligibility criterion for assistance. She gains $500 in labor income but loses $1,000 in benefits. So, even though she was promoted to a better-paying job, her income goes down.

Welfare, Recessions and the COVID-19 Pandemic

Another shortcoming of the current safety net structure is that the welfare system is not highly responsive to the economic cycle, making it largely unable to respond to higher poverty rates during recessions. This aspect is a direct expression of the work bias that informs the safety net: Most programs have work requirements, so people who are out of work are not eligible.

But recessions are precisely when people become poor due to losing their jobs. SNAP is a partial exception because it is available to jobless individuals, though assistance to those without dependent children is still limited, thus the reach of the program during economic downturns is far from universal.

The COVID-19 pandemic has brought to light how inadequate the safety net was, especially for the most vulnerable: children. The pandemic has affected a large number of individuals and families, swelling the poverty rate; some estimates put it back at the 1970s level of 25 percent. 3

The American Rescue Plan Act

This has made poverty more visible to many Americans who were previously unaffected by it. Though this is not the focus of this Economic Brief, we would be remiss not to notice how the COVID-19 pandemic amplified the interactions between poverty and racial inequality and prompted a debate on whether the welfare system can address this interplay, or the root causes of poverty. COVID-19 has also interrupted the upward trajectories of many families who had managed to climb the income ladder and reach the middle class. The American Rescue Plan Act that Congress recently passed attempts to address these unique circumstances.

The bill has two main components. First, it makes direct payments to individuals to cope with the effects of the pandemic and related severe economic downturn. Direct payments are almost universal. Thus, they are not addressed to combat persistent poverty but rather to relieve the temporary economic distress brought about by the pandemic.

Second, the bill reforms the safety net paradigm to better support working families with children. These provisions are more directly related to our discussion of the welfare system. These reforms include significantly expanding the size and scope of the EITC, CTC and the child and dependent care tax credit. These new benefits do not taper off with the number of children in households — unlike most other welfare programs — and have significantly higher income thresholds to alleviate the impact of benefits cliffs on low and middle earners.

These provisions plausibly signal a profound change in how voters — and the legislators they elect — envision the welfare system and its role in supporting families and children of lesser means. They recognize that we all have a vested interest in healthy, thriving children. Investing in children has high returns not just for individuals but also for society as a whole and, thus, is a worthy cause to spend public money on.

Though some of these provisions are slated to expire after one year and some after five years, I believe that the benefits from making them permanent would be substantial. My hope is that there is clear political will to consider such changes in a permanent way. Overall, both public opinion and policymakers have come to view a European-style safety net on American soil more favorably than ever before. I regard this as a momentous shift of the public opinion and a precious opportunity to reflect on what policies, programs and public interventions may lead more of us to share more broadly in the wealth our economy creates.

Claudia Macaluso is an economist in the Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.

" 2021 Poverty Guidelines ," Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, U.S. Department of Health & Human Services, Jan. 26, 2021.

Hilary W. Hoynes and Diane Whitmore Schanzenbach, " Safety Net Investments in Children ," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, March 8, 2018.

Zachary Parolin and Megan A. Curran, " Monthly Poverty Rate Declines to 13.2% in the United States in January 2021 (PDF) ," Center on Poverty and Social Policy, Columbia University, March 4, 2021.

This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its entirety. Please credit the author, source, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and include the italicized statement below.

Views expressed in this article are those of the author and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

Receive a notification when Economic Brief is posted online.

By submitting this form you agree to the Bank's Terms & Conditions and Privacy Notice.

As a new subscriber, you will need to confirm your request to receive email notifications from the Richmond Fed. Please click the  confirm subscription  link in the email to activate your request.  

If you do not receive a confirmation email, check your junk or spam folder as the email may have been diverted.

  • Tools and Resources
  • Customer Services
  • Conflict Studies
  • Development
  • Environment
  • Foreign Policy
  • Human Rights
  • International Law
  • Organization
  • International Relations Theory
  • Political Communication
  • Political Economy
  • Political Geography
  • Political Sociology
  • Politics and Sexuality and Gender
  • Qualitative Political Methodology
  • Quantitative Political Methodology
  • Security Studies
  • Share This Facebook LinkedIn Twitter

Article contents

Development, welfare policy, and the welfare state.

  • Gyu-Jin Hwang Gyu-Jin Hwang Department of Sociology and Social Policy, University of Sydney
  • https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190846626.013.145
  • Published in print: 01 March 2010
  • Published online: 30 November 2017

One of the most significant structural transformations in postwar capitalist democracies has been the rise of the welfare state. The theoretical intent of the traditional sociological and economic inquiry into the welfare state has focused less on trying to understand the welfare state itself and more on to what extent and under what conditions welfare provisions influence social and economic outcomes such as equality, employment, and labor market behavior. Over time, however, scholars have turned toward historical and political factors. G. Esping-Andersen identified three types of welfare state that seem incongruent with the real worlds of welfare capitalism: the “liberal,” “conservative/corporatist,” and “social democratic.” In contrast to the period until the mid-1980s that focused on welfare state expansion, the late 1980s saw the emergence of new streams of literature whose emphasis was on welfare state retrenchment. More recently, scholars have advanced the argument that the globalization of capital markets has effectively increased the power of capital over governments that seek to expand or maintain relatively high levels of social protection and taxation. Another notable trend is the increased intellectual interest in the relation between development and social policy and the growing interface between social policy and economic policy. A question that arises is whether distinctive welfare regimes have the ability to survive, particularly if their norms clash with those of the competition, or Schumpeterian workfare state.

  • welfare state
  • welfare state expansion
  • welfare state retrenchment
  • globalization
  • capital markets
  • development
  • social policy
  • economic policy
  • welfare capitalism

Introduction

The rise of the welfare state is perhaps the most significant structural transformation in postwar capitalist democracies. Yet the precise definition of the welfare state and exactly what constitutes it remains implicit. As Titmuss famously put it, the welfare state is an “indefinable abstraction” ( 1968 :124). Esping-Andersen also claims that a “remarkable attribute of the entire literature is its lack of much genuine interest in the welfare state as such […] the welfare state itself has generally received scant conceptual attention” ( 1990 :18). Indeed, the theoretical intent of the traditional sociological and economic inquiry into the welfare state has remained primarily concerned with the issues that are less about arriving at an understanding of the welfare state itself and more about addressing the social question as to what extent and under what conditions welfare provisions influence social and economic outcomes (e.g., equality, employment, and labor market behavior).

Over time, however, a significant degree of intellectual progress has been made as the socioeconomic inquiry into welfare has turned toward historical and political reasoning (cf. Hicks and Esping-Andersen 2005 ). More explicitly, the recent contribution of political science literature has shifted our attention to the political causes of welfare state development and cross-national variation. The welfare state is no longer being treated only as an independent variable but also as a dependent variable (van Kersbergen 2002 ; cf. Clasen and Siegel 2007 ). The theoretical progress advancing our understanding of welfare has grown in tandem with the specific historical development of the welfare state itself. During the early years of welfare state evolution, it was the economic and sociological approaches that almost exclusively dominated the welfare state expansion literature. In comparison, the retrenchment literature that has occupied the past two decades or so has been the domain of the political science approach (Green-Pedersen and Haverland 2002 ).

Against this backdrop, the most promising and intellectually inspiring progress was made as the emphasis turned to the confluence between different disciplinary traditions not only in answering why welfare states ever emerge and continue to develop, but also in accounting for why and how they differ. It is also where primary explanatory variables typically stressed by each disciplinary tradition are exchanged that we see many of the most convincing accounts of welfare state development. Over a long period, a series of discrete, incremental theoretical developments have coalesced into new theoretical paradigms, most of which share the comparative tradition of welfare state development. The most fruitful and intellectually stimulating pieces of research have emerged in this tradition not only because comparative research often challenges our preconceptions about the nature of best practices and exposes us to alternative ideas, but also because it reminds us that there are vast differences between the welfare states of today.

Explaining the Emergence of the Welfare State

The first generation of welfare state research was very much occupied with the question of why welfare states emerge, rather than why welfare states differ and how they differ. Instead of making explicit claims about what explains welfare state variations, the exercise was one of “devising laws” that could account for welfare state development and could be applied to a whole range of countries.

Central to this view, rooted in the functional or structural perspective, is that it is the “system that ‘wills’, and what happens is therefore easily interpreted as a functional requisite for the reproduction of society and economy” (Esping-Andersen 1990 :13). The emergence of welfare states is then a necessary change that balances the “system” because industrialization undermines the traditional social support mechanisms and causes new social needs, while economic growth provides the material basis for social policy expansion to meet these needs (Kerr et al. 1973 ; Wilensky 1975 ; Flora and Alber 1981 ). The logical conclusion drawn from this premise is one of convergence or technological determinism: all industrialized countries are growing more alike, meeting social needs through broadly similar forms of welfare intervention even though they have vastly different class, political, and cultural traditions (Wilensky with Lebeaux 1965 ; Rimlinger 1971 ; Wilensky 1975 ). It is therefore this industrial development that indirectly leads to greater social equality through higher welfare spending from which those in need benefit most (Kerr et al. 1973 ). The differences between welfare states are seen merely as being those of the degree of development. Hence societies are distinguished as being “welfare state leaders” or “welfare state laggards” rather than by distinctions of a more fundamental kind.

Clearly, this line of reasoning carries some compelling elements, not least because it offers a narrative that broadly fits with the historical path of development of the nations to which it was applied. Nonetheless, the core proposition of this logic of industrialism has been subject to a number of criticisms. First, as is the case with the transnational diffusion literature that predicts the sequence within which welfare programs are adopted but not their form (e.g., Abbott and DeViney 1992 ), it oversimplifies the process of policy development and ignores the important structural variations in the organizational and institutional features of welfare states.

Second, most studies in the tradition focus on welfare spending levels, which may be misleading as these levels tell us very little about where and how money is being spent. Third, the perspective has a significant problem in accounting for the timing of change within societies as well as in explaining varying time lags between industrialization and welfare development. Finally, industrial determinism places little emphasis on ideological factors and partisan politics, dismissing them as being “almost useless in explaining the origins and general development of the welfare state” (Wilensky 1975 :xiii) and considering the role of politics as merely a technological matter. The stability and the legitimacy of the state seem to be bound to technological success and prolonged economic growth (Carrier and Kendall 1971 :201).

Unlike industrial determinism, the logic of capitalism approach or neo-Marxism regards welfare state development as either a response to threats to the interests of the ruling class (i.e., the Bonapartist interpretation), or preemptive mechanisms to protect against such threats (i.e., the Bismarckian interpretation). For neo-Marxists, social provisions emerge and progress because state action promotes the needs or requirements of capital (accumulation); because states take preemptive action to prevent working class discontent (legitimation); and because states require a response to class conflict. The extent of class struggle becomes the key determinant. The development of the welfare state is therefore a necessary response to the contradictions within capitalism.

This neo-Marxist understanding of welfare state development is not uniform, however: there are at least three distinctive theoretical propositions within it. To start with, instrumentalists heavily criticize the core claim of pluralists that the state plays the role of neutral broker in mediating conflicts between various interests. Rather, for them, the state plays an instrumental role only to serve the capitalist’s interests. Miliband argues that “the intervention of the state is always and necessarily partisan: as a class state, it always intervenes for the purpose of maintaining the existing system of domination, even where it intervenes to mitigate the harness of that system of domination” ( 1977 :91). It is the capitalist who monopolizes economic organizations, exercises strong influence on political organizations, and determines social provision depending on the necessity for capital accumulation. Hence welfare reforms basically function as a form of social control rather than of social investment (Piven and Cloward 1971 ; Ginsburg 1979 ; Miliband 1991 ). Neither the basic structure of capitalist society nor the status, income, and political power of those who have already been influential are affected by social policy.

While this instrumental version of neo-Marxism comes closest to classical Marxist theory, a slight modification was made by those who stress the objective relation between the state and the capitalist. For them, it is the structure of the capitalist economy itself that enables agreement between the state function and the capitalists’ interests. Regardless of the capitalists’ influences, it is necessary for the state to preserve order and to sustain and enhance the conditions for capitalist economic activities. For this reason, the state might purse welfare provisions against the wishes of the capitalists. This will then strengthen the long-term stabilization of the economy (O’Connor 1973 ; 1984 ; Gough 1979 ; Offe 1984 ). In other words, the stability of a relatively autonomous state is a precondition for the political system to serve the interests of capitalists in the long run (Skocpol 1980 ). Of course, political conflict induced by the working class can be threatening to this political stability. Therefore, one of many important functions of the welfare state is to control and dismantle labor power. Similarly, welfare provisions can be expanded as part of a cooperative strategy of control (Piven and Cloward 1971 ).

In comparison, the third variation puts more emphasis on political class struggle. Instead of stressing the capitalist’s long-term or short-term interests, the development of the welfare state is interpreted as the outcome of a long political struggle between the working class and the capitalist and its allies. Known as the “power resources” approach, the fundamental power resources in advanced industrial societies are assumed to be divided and derive from labor control through the market mechanism and from political power through the capacity for collective action (Korpi 1989 ). Therefore, this working-class mobilization thesis explains that the development of the welfare state is dependent upon the strength of the labor movement and its political ability to implement collective welfare provisions through electoral control of the state. Similarly, proponents of the mass disruption thesis (see Piven and Cloward 1971 ) argue that social policies have improved because of the elite’s responses to protest by the poor and workers.

Strictly speaking, the class mobilization thesis should be seen not as a mere variation but as a distinctive theory that has its root in the neo-Marxist tradition because, unlike the logic of capitalism, which sees welfare spending as a means for capital to maintain its dominant position, it views welfare spending as a reflection of the political power gained by workers. It pays attention to the relative power of the “subordinate” class and regards variations in their power as being key in explaining variation in welfare state development.

Indeed, it is this thesis that has worked as a theoretical foundation for many. Nonetheless there are several valid objections. First, it places a strong emphasis on the harnessing of working-class power through its representative left-wing party. Indeed, a social democratic or labor party that represents the working class and highly centralized labor unions has been influential in driving welfare state expansion. However, socialist parties have not always played a dominant role in pushing forward welfare provision, especially in the early stage of welfare state development. In fact, many welfare programs have been introduced by liberal and/or conservative elites. Failure to account for the role and, indeed, power of non-leftist parties is its key weakness (Wilensky 1981 ; Borg and Castles 1981 ). Second, one of the assumptions that it makes is that the locus of decision-making power lies in parliaments. Thus great efforts have been made to collect data on leftist party representation in parliaments. But parliaments are not always the locus of power; indeed, extraparliamentary organizations often play a major role in policy development (George and Wilding 1994 ). Third, the ways in which working-class power is measured are problematic. Levels of unionization and percentages of votes gained by leftist parties in elections are typically used as proxy measures of working-class power (Korpi 1983 :39). Yet such measures treat power as a linear concept that ignores the role the working class plays in practice and is insensitive to the particularities of the ways in which a nation’s political institutions are organized, impacting on policy outcomes to varying degrees. And finally, as with much of the early work, this too was hampered by treating the development of welfare in a linear manner, using aggregate welfare expenditure as a proxy for welfare development.

The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism

A significant advance has been made in theorizing welfare state development. Yet much of early work tends to focus on finding one single powerful causal force within the well-established procedures and assumptions which are based on conceptions of linearity. Instead, the second generation of welfare state research began to identify salient interaction effects of multiple factors. In his early work, Esping-Andersen ( 1985 ), one of the most prominent adherents of the “working-class mobilization theory,” presented a classic formulation that distinguished social democratic models from others. Yet later, in his masterwork (Esping-Andersen 1990 ), he refined and significantly changed this duality, abandoning an ideal mode of one extreme or the other, and identified three separate routes of welfare state instead.

Breaking with his own past, Esping-Andersen ( 1990 ) points out that there are three particularly important factors at work: the nature of class mobilization (especially union structure); the opportunities to form class-political coalitions (especially those which incorporate the middle class); and the historical legacy of regime institutionalization. Significantly too, his conceptualization of the welfare state differs radically since it is not the level of social expenditure that is measured but the “degree to which individuals, or families, can uphold a socially acceptable standard of living independently of market participation” (Esping-Andersen 1990 :37). His measurement of social rights has led him to cluster welfare states around three different types, which he termed the “liberal,” “conservative/corporatist,” and “social democratic.”

The identification of these clusters itself was the key contribution of his work. Yet what is more compelling is his explanation for the reasons why particular nations developed their welfare provision along one particular path or another. He rejects the conception of an evolutionary development of social reform. For him, it is the interaction of three most important factors over time that produced a distinctive welfare state regime, much of which depended on the outcome of the power constellations during the formative phase of welfare states. Each of his three highly diverse regime types is organized around its own discrete logic of organization, stratification, and societal integration, and is given an “account that is much more nuanced, much more attentive to particularities and context – in a word, much more historical – than the older, unilinear, social scientific approach […] by taking a more contextualized and particularized approach to the development of social policy” (Baldwin 1992 :703). For Esping-Andersen ( 1990 :4), and Baldwin ( 1990 :299) too for that matter, “politics not only matters, but is decisive.”

Esping-Andersen’s work provided a platform for further research to a great extent, often coming from the challenges concerning the validity of his regime typology itself and the methodological flaws or oversight (Arts and Gelissen 2002 ). For instance, his ideal-typical treatment of regime types sits uncomfortably with the real worlds of welfare capitalism (Leibfried 1992 ; Castles and Mitchell 1993 ; Jones 1993 ; Ferrera 1996 ; Goodman and Peng 1996 ; Bonoli 1997 ; Castles 1998 ; White and Goodman 1998 ; Goodin et al. 1999 ; Holliday 2000 ). Kasza ( 2002 ) dismisses the usefulness of welfare regimes typology altogether for it generates too many bad fits and argues that policy-specific comparisons could provide better offerings instead. And Castles ( 1993 ) and his colleagues developed a “social protection by other means” approach which goes beyond state welfare. Viewed from a “families of nations” perspectives (Castles 1993 :xiii), there are more than three worlds of welfare. And this perspective, which is claimed to have a much wider policy span than regime interpretations, shows the coherence and persistence of the clustering of nations over time despite fundamental transformations of the international and domestic political economy (Castles and Obinger 2008 ). Room ( 2000 ) challenges Esping-Andersen’s analysis of decommodification, arguing that the Marxian notion of labor commodification is related not only to the economic consumption of labor but also to the loss of workers’ own opportunities for personal self-development as its consequence. And those who are dissatisfied by his interpretation of confining welfare state policies to the ones that are related to the labor contract argue that family policy, gendered division of labor, and social services have great importance for people’s standard of living regardless of whether or not they participate in the market (Lewis 1992 ; O’Connor 1993 ; 1996 ; Orloff 1993 ; 1996 ; Bambra 2005 ).

There is little doubt that Esping-Andersen’s major contribution to welfare state literature has been the concept of regime that denotes the ways in which welfare production is allocated among state, market, and households (see also Esping-Andersen 1999 ). His typology therefore does not confine itself to a specific social program or a type of welfare state. This construction of typology per se, however, is not entirely new. As Esping-Andersen himself acknowledges ( 1990 :20), Titmuss ( 1974 ) had, much earlier, identified three broad types of welfare state that were not too dissimilar. But what is distinctive here is that by stressing the importance of the particularities, not the regularities, welfare states are seen as “parts of complex, historically generated configurations”; the three worlds are qualitatively different and result from “the cumulative effects of a number of interdependent causal factors” (P. Pierson 2000 :809). In fact, Esping-Andersen is not alone in stressing historical and institutional factors. Indeed, much of the recent literature focuses on the argument that institutions play a key role in the determination of social and political outcomes. This forms the core of an important body of theory that has attracted increasing attention (see Baldwin 1992 ; Steinmo et al. 1992 ; Hall and Taylor 1996 ).

Institutions and the Politics of Welfare State Retrenchment

If the welfare state scholarship until the mid-1980s was dominated by works that examined the patterns, reasons, and ways of welfare state expansion, a significant shift began in the late 1980s. Particularly important was the upheaval of the new streams of literature, especially in relation to welfare state retrenchment that brought about a renewed emphasis on the role of institutions.

Evolved from the state-centered approach that criticizes the demand-driven approaches (e.g., social forces and conflict) involving passive and defensive actions from a government (Nordlinger 1981 ; Orloff and Skocpol 1984 ; Evans et al. 1985 ; Skocpol 1985 ; Skocpol and Amenta 1986 ; Ashford 1986 ; Almond 1988 ; Thelen and Steinmo 1992 ), scholars inspired by the institutional perspective began to stress the relationship between institutions and individual behavior and the distinctive political outcomes produced by this relationship (Steinmo et al. 1992 ; Hall and Taylor 1996 ). For them, “political life is characterized, not simply by a struggle over the allocation of resources, but also periodically by strife and uncertainty about the rules of the game within which this allocative process is carried out” (Krasner 1984 :225). Institutions establish the rules of the game, have long-term effects, foster stability by resisting dramatic change, and condition the opportunities and incentives for political action or inaction. They are thereby seen as intervening or intermediate variables that shape behavior and political outcomes (Krasner 1984 ; Gorges 2001 ). Taking the cue from Heclo’s ( 1974 ) illuminating parallels between the British and Swedish systems, where he stressed the critical importance of the inheritance of past policies in determining what is feasible at any given time, those inspired by this tradition have shifted the study of social policy away from a predominantly sociological perspective and into the realm of political science.

Historically informed work by the likes of Esping-Andersen ( 1990 ), Baldwin ( 1990 ), Immergut ( 1992 ) and Skocpol ( 1992 ) could all be grouped under this tradition, particularly in their articulation of the ways in which institutions and interests interact and in their claims that different paths of welfare state development have occurred over an extended period of time. It is recent debates surrounding globalization and the crisis of the welfare state, however, that have brought with them a fresh wave of theorizing in the realm of the institutional analysis of social policy.

Led by the work of P. Pierson ( 1994 ), who examined the attempts of conservative governments in the United Kingdom and the United States to cut back entitlements and weaken the political foundations of the welfare states, the politics of welfare state resilience came into the center stage of welfare state literature. Obviously, the coming into office of Margaret Thatcher in 1979 and of Ronald Reagan in 1981 sparked the academic interests, backed by conservative academics who claimed that the welfare state had become a significant source of social and economic problems instead of solutions (Murray 1984 ; Mead 1986 ; Marsland 1996 ). Also, significant changes in the economic environment practically ended one of the key foundations of the Golden Age welfare state: full employment (Esping-Andersen 1996 ).

For many welfare states, the conventional method of pursuing full employment has been through neo-Keynesian interventions. However, substantial shifts in productive activity have led to problems of job security and deterioration in pay for the jobs most subject to competition. Social foundations in postindustrial economies are also fundamentally different from those in the immediate postwar period (Esping-Andersen 1999 ). The postwar welfare state settlement was particularly directed at meeting needs during interruptions of the industrial wage, while care provisions were mostly assumed to be widely available informally. But the increasing rate of female labor participation led to demands for more equal opportunities and for care services. On the one hand, the growth in jobs was confined within the service sector, which tended to produce low or unskilled jobs. Low productivity growth in this sector compared to the manufacturing sector resulted in a downward pressure on wages. On the other hand, a low-skilled service sector afflicted with an abundance of female labor placed added pressure on wages and on care industries. Both generated a dilemma between job growth in the service sector and rising inequality (Esping-Andersen 1999 ). At the same time, the shift away from manufacturing tended to weaken union power and labor-associated political parties which were traditionally understood to be able to mobilize political pressure for welfare state expansion. The long list of formidable challenges and pressures that would potentially threaten the viability of the welfare state or even its survival exerted a combined pressure on traditional forms of state welfare both in terms of the range of options available for governments to promote employment and finance social provision, and in terms of increasing risks, needs, and demands as a result of labor market and family changes (Baumol 1967 ; Iversen and Wren 1998 ; Esping-Andersen 1999 ; P. Pierson 2001a ; Taylor-Gooby 2004 ). In short, the Golden Age of postwar welfare state expansion and its achievement were being viewed as having grown to its limits (cf. Flora 1986 ).

An increasingly interdependent world economy has also led many scholars to anticipate a significant degree of convergence (Scharpf 1991 ; Mishra 1996 ; Greider 1997 ; Martin and Schumann 1997 ; Gray 2002 ). Indeed, many countries have embraced the free market policy prescription as a solution to a range of policy problems, and some scholars predict a long-run decline – a race to the bottom – of the welfare state (Rodrik 1997 ; Allard and Danzir 2000 ) or a future of “permanent austerity” (P. Pierson 2001b :456). On the other hand, many studies of welfare state trajectories during the 1990s and the early years of the twenty-first century indicate that various welfare states respond differently to more or less similar sets of challenges, thereby negating a second coming of convergence thesis. The key to this divergence has been the politics of reform in each country, which has produced very different results and reform paths (Esping-Andersen 1999 ; Scharpf and Schmidt 2000a ; 2000b ; Huber and Stephens 2001 ; P. Pierson 2001a ).

The gap between the theoretical prediction and empirical reality gave rise to a new body of literature with substantially different aims. The problem was that the major explanatory accounts that dominated the heyday of welfare state expansion no longer seemed to provide convincing explanations, despite the claim that, as Esping-Andersen put it, “a theory that seeks to explain welfare-state growth should also be able to understand its retrenchment or decline” ( 1990 :32). For the scholars who advocate the welfare state “resilience” thesis, and P. Pierson ( 1996 ) in particular, theories about the “old politics” (Skocpol and Amenta 1986 ; Amenta 2003 ) that rely on socioeconomic functionalism and class-based power resources do not adequately explain developments after the end of the “Golden Age.” In other words, an increasing number of scholars began to identify that “politics” in the old sense, typified by class, parties, and unions, matters less and less for welfare state development and outcomes (Castles 1998 ; Stephens et al. 1999 ; Huber and Stephens 2001 ). Arguments about how to explain retrenchment or the resilience of existing welfare regimes began to focus on “new” political variables such as party systems, the logic of elections, political institutions, and political learning (Kuhnle 2000 ; P. Pierson 2001a ; Huber and Stephens 2001 ; Swank 2002 ). And these new factors at play make the logic of welfare state retrenchment very different from welfare state expansion (P. Pierson 1996 ). The key questions that dominated the academic inquiry of the late twentieth century were concerned with how and why existing welfare state regimes either seem to resist change or appear to change only incrementally according to a built-in regime logic that seems to reaffirm, if not aggravate, the difficulties that are typical for the regime (Starke 2006 ).

Protagonists of the “new politics” of welfare state development argue that major policy reforms are very difficult for two reasons. First, welfare provisions established during the period of postwar welfare state expansion created their own program-specific constituencies that subsequently led to the political unpopularity of cutbacks (Boeri et al. 2001 ; Taylor-Gooby 2001 ). Second, deeply entrenched welfare state institutions exert path-dependent rigidity. Any radical attempts to alter them are severely constrained by institutional structures and existing policy designs which are intrinsically very difficult to change also. Put simply, history matters for institutional development (P. Pierson 2004 ). A number of scholars have contributed to this resilience thesis by adding to or refining the argument by stressing a specific dimension of institutional analysis (Green-Pedersen and Haverland 2002 ). Overall, it is not a political logic that governs welfare state adaptation but an institutional logic that explains it.

The renewed emphasis on the functioning of institutions is broadly divided into two central considerations: the role of political institutions and their effects on the politics of welfare state reform; and the existing structures of social provision itself as welfare state institutions and their enduring effects. First, the institutional fragmentation of political systems makes welfare reform either more difficult or relatively easier. Large-scale retrenchment is often less likely to be envisaged in systems with a high degree of vertical and horizontal fragmentation of power due to the higher number of veto players. In systems with federalism, a bicameral parliament and inclusive electoral system provide various points of veto power which substantially reduce the room for governments to make reforms (Immergut 1992 ; Bonoli 2001 ; Huber and Stephens 2001 ; Swank 2001 ; Tsebelis 2002 ; Obinger et al. 2005 ). Conversely, those countries with a relatively small number of veto players could potentially enjoy a high concentration of political power. Nonetheless this remains a potential, for a concentration of power is often accompanied by a concentration of accountability (Pal and Weaver 2003 ). In those countries, for instance, dissatisfied voters can easily identify who is responsible for unpopular cutbacks. Politicians ultimately seek to be reelected, and hence try to avoid blame. In systems with a high degree of concentration of power, this “blame avoidance” (Weaver 1986 ) is more difficult than in other political systems where there are multiple actors who may have played significant roles at different stages and levels of decision-making processes (P. Pierson 1994 ). How, then, have those countries with a high degree of concentration of power managed to cut back on welfare entitlements? P. Pierson ( 1994 ) highlights three particular strategies governments use to avoid blame: compensation, obfuscation, and division. Those countries with power fragmentation may be better positioned to make retrenchment reforms but they are also equally vulnerable to blame sharing, while those countries with power concentration seem to have facilitated various strategies of retrenchment. Importantly, in this context, the execution of these strategies is often highly dependent upon institutional structures and existing policy designs.

Second, welfare state institutions themselves generate enduring effects. Social policies themselves, either intended or unintended (cf. Baldwin 1990 ; 1992 ), tend to create their own institutions that are often difficult to reform because, as most vividly outlined by the experience of pensions reform (e.g., Myles and Pierson 2001 ), institutional stickiness results in policies displaying “increasing returns.” Similarly, the argument is that past decisions constrain and impact upon future decisions to create a policy feedback effect whereby policies themselves become a central part of the policy-making process itself, rather than a mere outcome. Swank, for instance, argues that “aspects of programmatic structure have substantial impacts on the representation and the relative political capacities of pro-welfare interests” ( 2002 :52). Much earlier, Skocpol and Amenta captured this enduring effect of social policy by pointing out that “not only does politics create social policies; social policies also create politics. That is, once policies are enacted and implemented, they change the public agenda and patterns of group conflict through which subsequent policy changes occur” ( 1986 :149). Huber and Stephens ( 2001 ) go even further by pointing to the importance of the “ratchet effect,” where mass opposition against retrenchment in provisions, especially in the areas of pensions, education and healthcare, is often much stronger than support for their introduction.

The overall notion of path dependency is also present in the welfare regimes literature in the sense that distinctive welfare regimes produce distinct policy legacies which in turn largely determine both the extent of change and the types of change that may be possible. For Esping-Andersen, it was the “class coalitions in which the three welfare-state regime types were founded” ( 1990 :33) that generated the bearing of an existing welfare state structure on the current politics of change. For P. Pierson ( 1994 ; 2001a ; 2001b ), it was more of a sectoral dynamic that generated varying policy outcomes depending on the specific social policy areas in question. So, for instance, Myles and Pierson ( 2001 ) found that various trajectories followed by many nations in the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development in their pension reform do not neatly correspond with existing categorizations of those nations’ political cultures or historic welfare regimes. And they claim that examining preexisting pension arrangements provides the best explanation for the paths of reform chosen. In both cases, specific regimes, once consolidated, tend to produce unique policy path dependencies that in turn overdetermine solutions to new problems as well as strategies of welfare reform (cf. Scharpf and Schmidt 2000a ; 2000b ).

The idea of path dependency tending to lock the possibility of change into a predetermined trajectory seems somewhat overdone, however, ignoring the impact of subsequent changes in, for instance, power constellations. Indeed, preceding developments are often corrected or programs completed by complementary institutions. The accumulation of anomalies and those developments that may lead to greater internal inconsistency are all the more important, resulting in a possibly significant “paradigm shift” (P. Hall 1989 ; 1993 ). Even in the prototype Scandinavian redistributive welfare states, contribution-based schemes providing earnings-related benefits are increasingly supplementing, if not replacing, their universal flat-rate benefits systems. Occupationally separated schemes in conservative welfare regimes have approached near universalism, making the distinction between different occupational categories more or less meaningless. The fight of social democrats against the “exclusionary corporatism of narrow status-solidarity” or their “struggle for comprehensive, egalitarian, and universalist social security” (Esping-Andersen 1990 :65, 109) may no longer hold, not least because they were not even the chief advocates of universalism during the pre- 1945 liberal regimes in Scandinavia (Baldwin 1990 ).

Globalization and the Welfare Production Regime

Thus far, much of scholarly endeavor has been either about welfare state expansion or welfare state retrenchment, and accordingly the resilience of welfare states in relation to change. More recently, though, a number of research projects have begun to examine the new risk configurations that have emerged in the transition to postindustrial societies and that in turn have challenged welfare state arrangements that were established in the context of old, traditional risk contexts of industrial societies (Taylor-Gooby 2004 ; Bonoli 2005 ; Armingeon and Bonoli 2006 ). Numerous risk categories peculiar to postindustrial restructuring make an entry (Esping-Andersen 1999 ). Yet the central driving force of this postindustrial change is the notable rise in the international mobility of capital, which has an unprecedented impact on the welfare state. Swank has argued that Marxists, neoliberals, political scientists, economists, and popular analysts utilize “nearly identical reasoning to argue that the globalization of capital markets has effectively increased the power of capital over governments that seek to expand or maintain relatively high levels of social protection and taxation” ( 2001 :203).

Those subscribing to such views believe that the high-spending welfare regimes are coming under sustained pressure to reduce the size and cost of their welfare programs because failure to make “domestic investment conditions attractive to internationally mobile capital” (Evans and Cerny 2003 :55) will lead to capital flight from their economies. Drawing from the international relations literature, Evans and Cerny ( 2003 ) argue that the era of postindustrialism is remarkably different from the period that preceded it. In the postwar boom period, social policy was a relatively autonomous field of policy, a domestic issue that was unimpeded by wider economic concerns and so favorable to continual increases in state spending on welfare state activity. Yet “globalization has undermined these conditions.” Hence they anticipate the emergence of the “competition state,” which is “the successor to the welfare state, incorporating many of its features but reshaping them, sometimes quite drastically, to fit a globalizing world” ( 2003 :20, 24).

A similar line of argument has been developed in the sociological literature too. Building on work from regulation theory and ideas embedded in the notion of “post-Fordism” (cf. Burrows and Loader 1994 ), Jessop argues that “relative to the earlier post-war period, social policy is becoming more closely subordinated to economic policy […] and its delivery has been subject to a partial rollback of the state in favour of market forces and civil society,” not least because “the opening of national economies makes it harder to pursue social policy in isolation from economic policy” ( 2000 :171–2, 182). He claims that we have seen the death of the old-style Keynesian national welfare state, as typified in its ideal type by Esping-Andersen’s social democratic regime, and are seeing it replaced by what he calls the “Schumpeterian Workfare Postnational Regime,” a more modest offering characterized by more limited social rights and an emphasis on encouraging flexible labor markets.

Much of this begs serious questions about the ability of distinctive welfare regimes to survive, particularly if their norms clash with those of the competition, or Schumpeterian workfare state. While many have been keen to proclaim the end of the high-spending welfare state and welcome convergence on a more limited model of welfare, others have pointed to a continuing diversity in welfare provision and, crucially, the generally incremental nature of welfare reform, and consequently the continuation of distinct welfare regimes. Of particular significance is the considerable contribution made by the “varieties of capitalism” literature (Hall and Soskice 2001 ). By bringing together disparate strands of thinking in political science, economics, law, and business, it draws directly on Esping-Andersen’s analyses of regimes and then empirically observes a distinction between two types of contemporary capitalism: liberal market economies (LMEs), where economic coordination takes place primarily through market mechanisms and neoclassical frameworks provide a reasonable approximation of economic reality; and coordinated market economies (CMEs), in which nonmarket modes of coordination are prominent. These two types are the product of the ways in which particular combinations of institutions cluster in order to solve coordination problems that characterize the rules governing industrial relations, vocational training and education, corporate governance, interfirm relations, and internal relations with employees. According to this approach, what matters is not just an institutional context determined by the terms of competition in markets, but also these areas that are crucial to the firm’s operation. Firms are seen as the central actors in the economy whose behavior aggregates into national economic performance. In order for them to prosper, they must engage with others in multiple spheres of the political economy, where efficient coordination between them is key to success – all of this making this “varieties of capitalism” approach essentially actor centered.

Mares ( 2001 ) and Estevez-Abe et al. ( 2001 ) apply this approach to welfare production regimes, challenging the decades-long argument of the power of left parties and labor organizations as determining the extent of protection. According to them, contrary to the view that social policy is often thought to interfere with labor markets by raising labor costs or the reservation wage, social policies can also improve the operation of labor markets from the perspective of the firm. Unemployment benefits with high replacement rates, for instance, can improve the ability of firms to attract and retain pools of labor with high or specific skills. Disability benefits and early retirement benefits can also allow firms to release labor without violating implicit contracts about long-term employment. So they argue that specific types of political economies lead toward distinctive welfare states not least because relative abundance in certain skills in a given country constitutes a comparative advantage for firms in that country. Firms’ product market choices are constrained by the availability of the necessary skills, and the availability of specific skills in turn requires appropriate forms and levels of social protection. The existence of institutional complementarities, in short, is therefore the theoretical core of this highly influential approach. Similar to P. Pierson ’s claim that the importance of unions and left parties is likely to decline over time as welfare systems themselves generate broader constituencies of stakeholders and beneficiaries, the varieties of capitalism literature challenges or at least supplements the view that private sector actors have their own distinctive social policy interests depending on their underlying production strategies, negating once again the second coming of convergence thesis.

Pressures under economic globalization have urged us to think again about the traditionally protective functions of social policy and whether this particular dimension will be robust enough to capture the highly complex nature of welfare state retrenchment and/or restructuring in the postglobalization era. As discussed earlier, this has led to a significant rethinking of the sustainability of welfare state. Increasingly, much attention has been paid to identifying “productive” elements of welfare compared to its traditional “protective” traits (Giddens 2000 ; Holliday 2000 ; Room 2000 ; Midgley and Tang 2001 ; Castells and Himanen 2002 ; Powell and Barrientos 2004 ; Vis 2007 ) and to test the argument that “welfare states have shifted away from traditional protective functions towards a model of ‘productive welfare,’ characterized by a greater emphasis on investment in human capital” (Hudson and Kühner 2009 :34).

This widespread adoption of workfare represents a shift in focus to target more of a supporting and subjugated role of social policy vis-à-vis economic policy. This could be seen as a novel paradigm shift if we accepted the claim that “social security in the industrial countries is not intended to promote economic development, but rather to maintain income and provide support to those in need” (A. Hall and Midgley 2004 :234). However, this is at odds with the history of welfare policy development in Western Europe. In fact, the presupposed incompatibility of the hierarchical relationship between social policy and economic policy has been seriously challenged. For instance, the United Nations Research Institute for Social Development has launched a series of publications that are in line with welfare state renewal literature. Much work under the heading of Social Policy in a Development Context is organized in such a way as to point to the interlocking relationship between economic policy and social policy. Social policy goals are not necessarily in conflict with economic goals. Rather, they can be merged to build up a modern industrial market economy (Mkandawire 2004 ; Kangas and Palme 2005 ; Kwon 2005a ).

The experiences of the “late industrializers” in Western Europe show that social policy can be an effective instrument for economic development (C. Pierson 2005 ). The first social policy measure introduced by Bismarck was intended not only to undermine political support for the socialist movement in Prussia but also to facilitate industrialization. Hence these initial offerings were not designed to meet social needs and protect against social risks but to serve political and instrumental objectives (Rimlinger 1971 ). The Swedish invention of an active labor market policy in the 1930s was to battle against mass unemployment, not by providing income maintenance through creating social insurance but by equipping the recipients with the necessary skills to enable them to enter the labor market, thereby contributing to economic development (Dahl et al. 2001 ; Kangas and Palme 2005 ). Esping-Andersen calls this “Sweden’s celebrated ‘productivistic’ social policy; i.e. a pre-emptive policy to ensure that the labor market produces welfare and equality rather than social risks and poverty” ( 1997 :181). Like many developing countries, Nordic countries, too, in their early years of industrialization used their pension funds as a source of capital accumulation. In Sweden, for instance, supplementary pension funds were used to provide housing in urban areas, while the national pension funds in Finland were used to build up national basic infrastructure (Kangas and Palme 2005 ). Both the Bismarckian tradition and the Scandinavian social democratic tradition share this productivism: while the former represents traits of selective social investment in an authoritarian context, the latter portrays universal social investment in a democratic setting (Kwon 2005b ).

What often characterizes developing countries is not simply a lack of democracy but also, more importantly perhaps, the absence of a legitimate state and a pervasive formal labor market, both of which are often considered to be prerequisites for the development of social policy. The state in the South often lacks political legitimacy, hence being only a weak institutional actor. Importantly, statutory social policy institutions are weakly rooted and most people remain peripheral to the sphere of formal waged employment within a well-regulated capitalist economy. All the key ingredients that define the welfare state seem to be missing in the South. This may have been part of the reason why the literature on welfare state development has been “surprisingly insular, geographically confined to the advanced industrial states, and more particularly to an understanding of the European experience” (Haggard and Kaufman 2008 :21). In recent years, however, much progress has been made in advancing our understanding of the ways in which welfare states in other regions have developed.

A notable trend is the rise of intellectual interest in the relation between development and social policy and the increasing interface between social policy and economic policy. The renewed interest in the integration of social and economic policy is not new. In fact, it has long been argued that social policy is and should be an integral part of development (Myrdal 1974 ; Hardiman and Midgley 1982 ; Midgley 1995 ; Hall and Midgely 2004 ). A similar argument, yet with a much more systematic approach and analytic rigor, has been made by Wood and Gough ( 2004 ), arguing that although the “formal security of welfare” of the West is “the most satisfactory way of meeting the universal need for security and well-being” ( 2004 :324), transforming the Global South’s “insecurity and welfare regimes” along these lines is neither feasible nor desirable, not least because they are constructed in relation to the existing structural division of societal power particular to them. Adapting the Esping-Andersen’s model of welfare state regimes ( 1990 ; 1999 ), Gough et al. ( 2004 ) have developed a more universal welfare regimes framework, identifying two further families of regime types: informal security regimes and insecurity regimes. In each, the relative strengths of key institutional components (state, market, community, and household) determine the dominant livelihood strategies pursued. Together with the welfare outcomes (e.g., human development index, millennium development goals, need satisfaction, subjective well-being), this in turn shapes the ways that populations are stratified and the dominant forms of social and political mobilizations by shaping the means of recuperation open to different groups through exit, voice, or loyalty. These reproduction consequences then reinforce the institutional structures, thus generating a path dependent form of development. Yet they can also undermine the macro-institutional conditions, thus setting in motion a process of change. In the context of the South, social policy can act as a means to an end, improving human welfare and contributing, both positively and negatively, to shaping and maintaining social structure and to distributing political power.

Compared to the work of Gough et al., Haggard and Kaufman present a perspective that is much more historically oriented and driven by political economy in their exploration of distinctive welfare trajectories in middle income countries of Latin America, East Asia, and Eastern Europe. Core to their explanatory account is an “extended historical consideration of how critical realignments, development strategies, and regime type interacted in altogether different regional settings” ( 2008 :19–20). The key set of analytical factors is largely drawn from the ones that identified the experiences of the advanced welfare states: the significance of distributive coalitions and economic interests; the performance of the economy and its organization; and political institutions, with particular focus on the influence of regime type. There are a number of forces at work which distinguish the developmental trajectories of welfare in one region from another. Haggard and Kaufman argue that “no single prescription – with respect to parties, interest groups or even social policies themselves – will provide a template for addressing the problems of injustice, inequality, and poverty that plague us. The opportunities to rectify past injustices are inevitably constrained by history” ( 2008 :363).

It should be clear by now that no single determining factor explains welfare state expansion, retrenchment, and change. Over time, a number of factors have been suggested, tested, and modified to prove their analytic power in explaining welfare state change. The intellectual progress on the development of welfare owes much to the multiplicity of various factors at work, with varying degrees of influence, over an extended period of time, and sitting at the centre of this are those who take the historically informed institutional analysis seriously. Haggard and Kaufman’s inspiring work reminds us how fruitful the theoretical synthesis of previous comparative welfare state research can become. The application of the usual suspects in accounting for welfare development in advanced industries has been extended to wider contexts, generating lively debates on the possible way(s) forward for broadening our understanding of development, welfare policy, and the welfare state. This is critical not least because it has important implications for validating the positivity between the labour power and the progressivity of the welfare state, the benefits of democracy, and the possibility of a broader range of economic alternatives (Haggard and Kaufman 2008 :21–4). The merits of the power-resource approach, the effects of economic structure and performance on welfare commitments, and the enduring effects of institutions, all of these powerful explanatory variables will continue to enter the new testing ground. And most likely, it will be the comparative research in a historical setting that provides the context within which future possibilities are tested, both in theoretical and in empirical terms.

  • Abbott, A. , and DeViney, S. (1992) The Welfare State as Transnational Event: Evidence from Sequences of Policy Adoption. Social Science History 16 (2), 245–74.
  • Allard, S.W. , and Danziger, S. (2000) Welfare Magnets: Myth or Reality? Journal of Politics 62 (2), 350–68.
  • Almond, G.A. (1988) The Return of the State. American Political Science Review 82 (3), 853–74.
  • Amenta, E. (2003) What We Know about the Development of Social Policy. In J. Mahoney and D. Rueschemeyer (eds.) Comparative Historical Analysis in the Social Sciences . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 91–130.
  • Armingeon, K. , and Bonoli, G. (eds.) (2006) The Politics of Postindustrial Welfare States: Adapting Post-war Social Policies to New Social Risks . Abingdon, UK: Routledge.
  • Arts, W.A. , and Gelissen, J. (2002) Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism or More? A State-of-the-Art Report. Journal of European Social Policy 12 (2), 137–58.
  • Ashford, D.E. (1986) The Emergence of the Welfare States . Oxford: Blackwell.
  • Baldwin, P. (1990) The Politics of Social Solidarity: The Class Basis of the European Welfare States, 1875–1975 . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Baldwin, P. (1992) The Welfare State for Historians: A Review Article. Comparative Studies in Society and History 34 (4), 695–707.
  • Bambra, C. (2005) Cash versus Services: “Worlds of Welfare” and the Decommodification of Cash Benefits and Health Care Services. Journal of Social Policy 34 (2), 195–213.
  • Baumol, W. (1967) The Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth. American Economic Review 52 (3), 415–26.
  • Boeri, T. , Borsch-Supan, A. , and Tabellini, G. (2001) Would You Like to Shrink the Welfare State? A Survey of European Citizens. Economic Policy 16 (32), 7–50.
  • Bonoli, G. (1997) Classifying Welfare States: A Two-Dimension Approach. Journal of Social Policy 26 (3), 351–72.
  • Bonoli, G. (2001) Political Institutions, Veto Points, and the Process of Welfare State Adaptation. In P. Pierson (ed.) The New Politics of the Welfare State . Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 238–64.
  • Bonoli, G. (2005) The Politics of the New Social Policies: Providing Coverage against New Social Risks in Mature Welfare States. Policy and Politics 33 (3), 431–49.
  • Borg, S.G. , and Castles, F.G. (1981) The Influence of the Political Right on Public Income Maintenance Expenditure and Equality. Political Studies 29 (4), 604–21.
  • Burrows, R. , and Loader, B. (eds.) (1994) Towards a Post-Fordist Welfare State? London: Routledge.
  • Carrier, J. , and Kendall, I. (1971) Social Policy and Social Change: Explanations of the Development of Social Policy. Journal of Social Policy 2 (3), 209–24.
  • Castells, M. , and Himanen, P. (2002) The Information Society and the Welfare State: The Finnish Model . Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Castles, F.G. (ed.) (1993) Families of Nations: Patterns of Public Policy in Western Democracies . Aldershot, UK: Dartmouth.
  • Castles, F.G. (1998) Comparative Public Policy: Patterns of Post-war Transformation . Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
  • Castles, F.G. , and Mitchell, D. (1993) Worlds of Welfare and Families of Nations. In F.G. Castles (ed.) Families of Nations: Patterns of Public Policy in Western Democracies . Aldershot: Dartmouth, pp. 93–128.
  • Castles, F.G. , and Obinger, H. (2008) Worlds, Families, Regimes: Country Clusters in European and OECD Area Public Policy. West European Politics 31 (1–2), 321–44.
  • Clasen, J. , and Siegel, N.A. (eds.) (2007) Investigating Welfare State Change: The “Dependent Variable Problem” in Comparative Analysis . Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
  • Dahl, E. , Drøpping, J.A. , and Lødemel, I. (2001) Norway: Relevance of the Social Development Model for Post-war Welfare Policy. International Journal of Social Welfare 10 (4), 300–8.
  • Esping-Andersen, G. (1985) Politics against Markets: The Social Democratic Road to Power . Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Esping-Andersen, G. (1990) Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism . Cambridge: Polity.
  • Esping-Andersen, G. (1996) After the Golden Age? Welfare State Dilemmas in a Global Economy. In G. Esping-Andersen (ed.) Welfare States in Transition: National Adaptations in Global Economies . London: Sage, pp. 1–31.
  • Esping-Andersen, G. (1997) Hybrid or Unique? The Japanese Welfare State between Europe and America. Journal of European Social Policy 7 (3), 179–89.
  • Esping-Andersen, G. (1999) Social Foundations of Postindustrial Economies . Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Estevez-Abe, M. , Iversen, T. , and Soskice, D. (2001) Social Protection and the Formation of Skills: A Reinterpretation of the Welfare State. In P.A. Hall and D. Soskice (eds.) Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage . Oxford: Oxford University Press, 145–83.
  • Evans, M. , and Cerny, P. (2003) Globalization and Social Policy. In N. Ellison and C. Pierson (eds.) Developments in British Social Policy 2 . Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 19–40.
  • Evans, P.B. , Rueschemeyer, D. , and Skocpol, T. (eds.) (1985) Bringing the State Back In . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Ferrera, M. (1996) The Southern Model of Welfare in Social Europe. Journal of European Social Policy 6 (1), 17–37.
  • Flora, P. (ed.) (1986) Growth to Limits: The Western European Welfare States since World War II . Berlin: de Gruyter.
  • Flora, P. , and Alber, J. (1981) Modernization, Democratization, and the Development of Welfare States in Western Europe. In P. Flora and A.J. Heidenheimer (eds.) The Development of Welfare States in Europe and America . London: Transaction, pp. 37–80.
  • George, V. , and Wilding, P. (1994) Welfare and Ideology . London: Harvester Wheatsheaf.
  • Giddens, A. (2000) The Third Way and Its Critics . Cambridge: Polity.
  • Ginsburg, N. (1979) Class, Capital and Social Policy . London: Macmillan.
  • Goodin, R.E. , Headey, B. , Muffels, R. , and Dirven, H.-J. (1999) The Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Goodman, R. , and Peng, I. (1996) The East Asian Welfare States: Peripatetic Learning, Adaptive Change, and Nation-building. In G. Esping-Andersen (ed.) Welfare States in Transition . London: Sage, pp. 192–224.
  • Gorges, M.J. (2001) The New Institutionalism and the Study of the European Union: The Case of the Social Dialogue. West European Politics 24 (4), 152–68.
  • Gough, I. (1979) The Political Economy of the Welfare State . London: Macmillan.
  • Gough, I. , and Wood, G. with Barrientos, A. , Bevan, P. , Davis, P. , and Room, G. (eds.) (2004) Insecurity and Welfare Regimes in Asia, Africa and Latin America: Social Policy in Development Context . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Gray, J. (2002) False Dawn: The Delusions of Global Capitalism . London: Granta Books.
  • Green-Pedersen, C. , and Haverland, M. (2002) Review Essay: The New Politics and Scholarship of the Welfare State. Journal of European Social Policy 12 (1), 34–51.
  • Greider, W. (1997) One World Ready or Not: The Manic Logic of Global Capitalism . New York: Simon and Schuster.
  • Haggard, S. , and Kaufman, R.R. (2008) Development, Democracy, and Welfare States: Latin America, East Asia, and Eastern Europe . Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Hall, A. , and Midgely, J. (2004) Social Policy for Development . London: Sage.
  • Hall, P.A. (ed.) (1989) The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism across Nations . Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Hall, P.A. (1993) Policy Paradigms, Social Learning, and the State: The Case of Economic Policymaking in Britain. Comparative Politics 25 (3), 275–96.
  • Hall, P.A. , and Soskice, D. (eds.) (2001) Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage . Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Hall, P.A. , and Taylor, R.C.R. (1996) Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms. Political Studies 44 (5), 936–57.
  • Hardiman, M. , and Midgley, J. (1982) The Social Dimensions of Development: Social Policy and Planning in the Third World . London: John Wiley.
  • Heclo, H. (1974) Modern Social Politics in Britain and Sweden: From Relief to Income Maintenance . New Haven: Yale University Press.
  • Hicks, A. , and Esping-Andersen, G. (2005) Comparative and Historical Studies of Public Policy and the Welfare State. In T. Janoski , R. Alford , A. Hicks and M.A. Schwartz (eds.) The Handbook of Political Sociology . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 509–25.
  • Holliday, I. (2000) Productivist Welfare Capitalism: Social Policy in East Asia. Political Studies 48 (4), 706–23.
  • Huber, E. , and Stephens, J.D. (2001) Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties and Policies in Global Markets . Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
  • Hudson, J. , and Kühner, S. (2009) Towards Productive Welfare? A Comparative Analysis of 23 OECD Countries. Journal of European Social Policy 19 (1), 32–46.
  • Immergut, E.M. (1992) Health Politics: Interests and Institutions in Western Europe . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Iversen, T. , and Wren, A. (1998) Equality, Employment and Budgetary Restraint: The Trilemma of the Service Economy. World Politics 50 (4), 507–46.
  • Jessop, B. (2000) From the KWNS to the SWPR. In G. Lewis , S. Gewirtz and J. Clarke (eds.) Rethinking Social Policy . London: Sage, pp. 171–84.
  • Jones, C. (1993) The Pacific Challenge: Confucian Welfare States. In C. Jones (ed.) New Perspectives on the Welfare State in Europe . London: Routledge, pp. 198–217.
  • Kangas, O. , and Palme, J. (eds.) (2005) Social Policy and Economic Development in the Nordic Countries . Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Kasza, G.J. (2002) The Illusion of Welfare “Regimes.” Journal of Social Policy 31 (2), 271–87.
  • Kerr, C. , Dunlop, J.T. , Harbison, F.H. , and Myers, C.A. (1973) Industrialism and Industrial Man: The Problems of Labour and Management in Economic Growth . Harmondsworth, UK: Penguin.
  • Korpi, W. (1983) The Democratic Class Struggle . London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
  • Korpi, W. (1989) Power Politics and State Autonomy in the Development of Social Citizenship: Social Rights during Sickness in Eighteen OECD Countries since 1930. American Sociological Review 54 (3), 309–28.
  • Krasner, S.D. (1984) Approaches to the State. Comparative Politics 16 (2), 223–46.
  • Kuhnle, S. (2000) European Welfare Lessons of the 1990s. In S. Kuhnle (ed.) Survival of the European Welfare State . London: Routledge, pp. 234–8.
  • Kwon, H.-J. (ed.) (2005a) Transforming the Developmental Welfare State in East Asia: Social Policy in a Development Context . London: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Kwon, H.-J. (2005b) Review Article: Social Policy and Development in Global Context. Social Policy and Society 4 (4), 467–73.
  • Leibfried, S. (1992) Towards a European Welfare State: On Integrating Poverty Regimes into the European Community. In Z. Ferge and J.E. Kolberg (eds.) Social Policy in a Changing Europe . Boulder: Westview, pp. 227–59.
  • Lewis, J. (1992) Gender and the Development of Welfare Regimes. Journal of European Social Policy 2 (3), 157–73.
  • Mares, I. (2001) Firms and the Welfare State: When, Why, and How Does Social Policy Matter to Employers? In P.A. Hall and D. Soskice (eds.) Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage . Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 184–212.
  • Marsland, D. (1996) Welfare or Welfare State? Contradictions and Dilemmas in Social Policy . London: Macmillan.
  • Martin, H.P. , and Schumann, H. (1997) The Global Trap: Globalization and the Assault on Democracy and Prosperity . London: Zed Books.
  • Mead, L. (1986) Beyond Entitlement: The Social Obligations of Citizenship . New York: Free Press.
  • Midgley, J. (1995) Social Development: The Developmental Perspective in Social Welfare . London: Sage.
  • Midgley, J. , and Tang, K.-I. (2001) Social Policy, Economic Growth and Developmental Welfare. International Journal of Social Welfare 10 (4), 244–52.
  • Miliband, R. (1977) Marxism and Politics . Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Miliband, R. (1991) Divided Societies: Class Struggle in Contemporary Capitalism . Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Mishra, R. (1996) The Welfare of Nations. In R. Boyer and D. Drache (eds.) States against Markets: The Limits of Globalization . London: Routledge, pp. 238–51.
  • Mkandawire, T. (ed.) (2004) Social Policy in a Development Context . London: Palgrave Macmillan.
  • Murray, C.A. (1984) Losing Ground: American Social Policy , 1950–1980. New York: Basic Books.
  • Myles, J. , and Pierson, P. (2001) The Comparative Political Economy of Pension Reform. In P. Pierson (ed.) The New Politics of the Welfare State , Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 305–33.
  • Myrdal, G. (1974) What is Development? Journal of Economic Issues 8 (4), 729–36.
  • Nordlinger, E.A. (1981) On the Autonomy of the Democratic State . Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
  • Obinger, H. , Leibfried, S. , and Castles, F.G. (eds.) (2005) Federalism and the Welfare State: New World and European Experiences . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • O’Connor, J. (1973) The Fiscal Crisis of the State . New York: St. Martin’s Press.
  • O’Connor, J. (1984) Accumulation Crisis . Oxford: Blackwell.
  • O’Connor, J.S. (1993) Gender, Class and Citizenship in the Comparative Analysis of Welfare State Regimes: Theoretical and Methodological Issues. British Journal of Sociology 44 (3), 501–18.
  • O’Connor, J.S. (1996) From Women in the Welfare State to Gendering Welfare Regimes. Current Sociology 44 (2), 1–24.
  • Offe, C. (1984) Contradictions of the Welfare State . London: Hutchinson Education.
  • Orloff, A.S. (1993) Gender and the Social Rights of Citizenship: The Comparative Analysis of Gender Relations and Welfare States. American Sociological Review 58 (3), 303–28.
  • Orloff, A.S. (1996) Gender in the Welfare State. Annual Review of Sociology 22, 51–78.
  • Orloff, A.S. , and Skocpol, T. (1984) Why Not Equal Protection? Explaining the Politics of Public Social Spending in Britain, 1990–1991 and the United States, 1980s–1920. American Sociological Review 49 (6), 726–50.
  • Pal, L.A. , and Weaver, R.K. (2003) Conclusions. In L.A. Pal and R.K. Weaver (eds.) The Government Taketh Away: The Politics of Pain in the United States and Canada . Washington: Georgetown University Press, pp. 293–328.
  • Pierson, C. (2005) “Late Industrializers” and the Development of Welfare Regimes. Acta Politica 40 (4), 395–418.
  • Pierson, P. (1994) Dismantling the Welfare State? Regan, Thatcher, and the Politics of Retrenchment . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Pierson, P. (1996) The New Politics of the Welfare State. World Politics 48 (2), 143–79.
  • Pierson, P. (2000) Three Worlds of Welfare State Research. Comparative Political Studies 33 (6/7), 791–821.
  • Pierson, P. (ed.) (2001a) The New Politics of the Welfare State . Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Pierson, P. (2001b) Coping with Permanent Austerity: Welfare State Restructuring in Affluent Democracies. In P. Pierson (ed.) The New Politics of the Welfare State . Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 410–56.
  • Pierson, P. (2004) Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Political Analysis . Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Piven, F.F. , and Cloward, R. (1971) Regulating the Poor: The Functions of Public Welfare . New York: Pantheon Books.
  • Powell, M. , and Barrientos, A. (2004) Welfare Regimes and the Welfare Mix. European Journal of Political Research 43 (1), 83–105.
  • Rimlinger, G.V. (1971) Welfare Policy and Industrialization in Europe, America and Russia . New York: John Wiley.
  • Rodrik, D. (1997) Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington: Institute for International Economics.
  • Room, G. (2000) Commodification and Decommodification: A Developmental Critique. Policy and Politics 28 (3), 331–51.
  • Scharpf, F.W. (1991) Crisis and Choice in European Social Democracy . Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
  • Scharpf, F.W. , and Schmidt, V.A. (eds.) (2000a) Welfare and Work in the Open Economy, Volume 1: From Vulnerability to Competitiveness . Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Scharpf, F.W. , and Schmidt, V.A. (eds.) (2000b) Welfare and Work in the Open Economy, volume 2: Diverse Responses to Common Challenges , Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Skocpol, T. (1980) Political Response to Capitalist Crisis: Neo-Marxist Theories of the State and the Case of the New Deal. Politics and Society 10 (2), 155–201.
  • Skocpol, T. (1985) Bringing the State Back In: Strategies of Analysis in Current Research. In P.B. Evans , D. Rueschemeyer and T. Skocpol (eds.) Bringing the State Back In . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 3–43.
  • Skocpol, T. (1992) Protecting Soldiers and Mothers: The Political Origins of Social Policy in the United States . Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
  • Skocpol, T. , and Amenta, E. (1986) States and Social Policies. Annual Review of Sociology 12, 131–57.
  • Starke, P. (2006) The Politics of Welfare State Retrenchment: A Literature Review. Social Policy and Administration 40 (1), 104–20.
  • Steinmo, S. , Thelen, K. , and Longstreth, F. (eds.) (1992) Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Stephens, J.D. , Huber, E. , and Ray, L. (1999) The Welfare State in Hard Times. In H. Kitschelt , G. Marks , P. Lange and J.D. Stephens (eds.) Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 164–93.
  • Swank, D. (2001) Political Institutions and Welfare State Restructuring: The Impact of Institutions on Social Policy Change in Developed Democracies. In P. Pierson (ed.) The New Politics of the Welfare State . Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 197–237.
  • Swank, D. (2002) Global Capital, Political Institutions, and Policy Change in Developed Welfare States , Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Taylor-Gooby, P. (2001) Sustaining State Welfare in Hard Times: Who Will Foot the Bill? Journal of European Social Policy 11 (2), 133–47.
  • Taylor-Gooby, P. (2004) New Risks, New Welfare: The Transformation of the European Welfare State . Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Thelen, K. , and Steinmo, S. (1992) Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics. In S. Steinmo , K. Thelen and F. Longstreth (eds.) Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1–32.
  • Titmuss, R. (1968) Commitment to Welfare . London: Allen and Unwin.
  • Titmuss, R. (1974) Social Policy: An Introduction . London: Allen and Unwin.
  • Tsebelis, G. (2002) Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work . Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • van Kersbergen, K. (2002) The Politics of Welfare State Reform. Swiss Political Science Review 8 (1), 1–20.
  • Vis, B. (2007) States of Welfare or States of Workfare? Welfare State Restructuring in 16 Capitalist Democracies, 1985–2002. Policy and Politics 35 (1), 105–22.
  • Weaver, R.K. (1986) The Politics of Blame Avoidance. Journal of Public Policy 6 (4), 371–98.
  • White, G. , and Goodman, R. (1998) Welfare Orientalism and the Search for an East Asian Welfare Model. In R. Goodman , G. White and H. Kwon (eds.) The East Asian Welfare Model: Welfare Orientalism and the State . London: Routledge, pp. 3–24.
  • Wilensky, H.L. (1975) The Welfare State and Equality: Structural and Ideological Roots of Public Expenditures . Berkeley: University of California Press.
  • Wilensky, H.L. (1981) Leftism, Catholicism, and Democratic Corporatism: The Role of Political Parties in Recent Welfare State Development. In P. Flora and A.J. Heidenheimer (eds.) The Development of Welfare States in Europe and America . New Brunswick: Transaction, pp. 345–82.
  • Wilensky, H.L. , with Lebeaux, C.N. (1965) Industrial Society and Social Welfare: The Impact of Industrialization on the Supply and Organization of Social Welfare Services in the United States . New York: Free Press.
  • Wood, G. , and Gough, I. (2004) Conclusion: Rethinking Social Policy in Development Context. In I. Gough and G. Wood with A. Barrientos , P. Bevan , P. Davis and G. Room (eds.) Insecurity and Welfare Regimes in Asia, Africa and Latin America: Social Policy in Development Contexts . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 312–26.

Links to Digital Materials

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. At www.oecd.org , accessed Jul. 2009. The website of the OECD provides a framework for discussion, comparisons and coordination of domestic and international economic and social policy. It contains useful reports, statistics and working papers, including social protection arrangements and a database of social expenditure in the high income countries.

Social Security Programs throughout the World . At www.ssa.gov/policy/docs/progdesc/ssptw , accessed Jul. 2009. Publication of the US Social Security Administration providing concise information on the coverage, qualifying conditions and benefit levels, and the financing of the main social security programs in 170 countries all over the world.

Mutual Information System on Social Protection in the Member States of the European Union 1(MISSOC). At http://ec.europa.eu/employment_social/spsi/missoc_en.htm , accessed Jul. 2009. Provides basic information regarding social protection measures in the Member States of the European Union and of the European Economic Area. It is therefore smaller in scope but provides more detail and is strongly embedded in social policy discussions at the European level.

United Nations Research Institute for Social Development. At www.unrisd.org , accessed Jul. 2009. Here UNRISD provides various research reports and conference news, working papers, and academic publications. Key research programs include social policy and development, democracy, governance and well-being, civil society and social movements, markets, business and regulation, identities, conflict and cohesion, as well as gender and development.

Asian Development Bank. At www.adb.org , accessed Jul. 2009. Provides key statistics on social and welfare issues, including social inequality, unemployment and social security spending, and is a valuable point of reference for those interested in Asia.

Printed from Oxford Research Encyclopedias, International Studies. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a single article for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).

date: 04 September 2024

  • Cookie Policy
  • Privacy Policy
  • Legal Notice
  • Accessibility
  • [185.66.14.236]
  • 185.66.14.236

Character limit 500 /500

The British Welfare System Essay

  • To find inspiration for your paper and overcome writer’s block
  • As a source of information (ensure proper referencing)
  • As a template for you assignment

Report Findings

Reference list.

This paper is, for the most part, analysis and evaluation of the social welfare system in Britain. It will begin with a study of the history of the system and later delve into a discussion of the various theories that inform social welfare. It will then progress into focusing on the two most relevant theories to the system in Britain. Furthermore, it will seek to assess the impact of the social welfare system in Britain.

Finally, the paper will conclude with an examination as to whether or not there are health inequalities in the country. It will conduct the examination by comparing the current situation with the various theories which have been used to explain health disparities. In a nutshell, therefore, this paper is a study of how the social welfare system has impacted the quality of life of the citizens in the country and, more specifically, if it has had any positive implications of the problem of inequality between the classes.

Evaluation of the Nature of British State Welfare Provision

British welfare provisions have their root in the Act for the relief of the poor, which was enacted in 1601. This was a law whose tentacles extended to almost every facet of Victorian life and labour (Englander 2013). The laws came about as a result of the liberal reforms 1601-1914. These reforms were a watershed occurrence because they marked the departure by the government of their laissez-faire approach to governance, which provided that the government should not interfere in matters of social life (Rowntree, n.d.).

For example, the poor laws now regulated employment, housing, marriage, education, migration, and charity, which were matters that touched closely on the social lives of the subjects. The new approach taken by the government was a collectivist approach whereby the government sought to accept responsibility for those sections of the society that were worse off and could not provide for themselves (Rowntree, n.d.).

These laws also carried a lot of social and political significance in that they described and regulated the relations between the rich and the have-nots and furthermore provided a lot of controversial issues that fueled the politics of the day (Englander 2013). The poor laws were developed at a time when England was going through a widespread and dreadful economic depression. They were, therefore, enacted to secure order and also to ensure that the general good of the kingdom was maintained.

They remained in force for over two centuries, with minor changes being made from time to time. The laws identified three categories of people that were considered as dependents, namely; the vagrant, involuntarily employed and the helpless (Hansan 2011). The purpose of these laws was to provide clear guidelines on how each category of dependents would be dealt with.

Before the coming into force of the poor laws, the poor in the society majorly received help from Christian charities which were set up by either churches or monasteries (Spicker 2014). The institutional framework that was put in place by the new legislation to secure the welfare of the poor was the local government which was also known as the parish. They were empowered to raise taxes to establish almshouses for the dependents (Hansan 2011).

Parents were also required by law to maintain their children and grandchildren, and the reverse was also required where the parents were unemployed and therefore dependents. Those children whose parents could not support them were committed into forced apprenticeships and also, any able bodied persons or vagrants who refused to work were either fined of committed in a correctional house (Hansan 2011).

The Beveridge report, which was authored and presented by Sir William Beveridge in 1942, is considered the blueprint for the modern welfare state. It led to the establishment of a social security system and also, a National Health system at the close of the Second World War. In a nutshell, it required that all working persons should pay a weekly fee to the state which would then be used to provide welfare services to the sick, unemployed, widowed and retired. Ideally, this new system aimed to provide for a minimum standard of living below which no person in the state would fall (The National Archives, n.d.).

From this history, it can be gleaned that the main benefits of the poor laws were to provide for the needy in a society which task was later adopted by the current state welfare provisions regarding social security. Although the idea behind the laws was noble, some commentators argue that the result was not all positive, especially because the workhouses began to be regarded by the poor as prisons. Fear of being condemned into the workhouses, in fact, led to numerous riots in the period during which the laws were in force.

Theories of Welfare

Social democratic theory.

Its most striking claim is that the material interests of the different classes which make up the society are the fuel for both the opposition and the support that drives the welfare state (Mau & Veghte 2007). It mainly focuses on the classes as the primary drivers of the social welfare state with their varied interests being voiced politically through the right and left wing parties.

The Institutional Model of Welfare

This model of well-being is premised on the assumption that welfare provision is a normal and natural function of the modern industrial society. This theory, moreover, provides that it is the duty of the state to provide a reasonable standard of living for all its citizens (Harris 2000).

Marxist Theory

This theory asserts that there can be no welfare in a capitalist state (Roos 1973). Marx, who is the originator of this theory, focuses on the society as being divided into the owners of capital and the proletariat who act as their workers. With regards to welfare, he avers that the proletariat is deprived of actual needs and not just their realization (Roos 1973).

Feminist Theory

Feminist argument contends that all political and economic power is in the hands of men and therefore, that the welfare and health system of a state reflects the interests of men without due consideration to those of women. They further assert that the mainstream social welfare system is deficient because it is gender blind as it makes no room for the different experiences of men and women as players in the state.

The Market Liberal Theory

Liberals operate with the conviction that the state has no right to interfere with their personal choices. They usually divide the state into the private and public sphere and limit the government’s sphere of influence within the public domain. According to the liberals, therefore, the government has no power to reorder the private sphere of the citizens through the provision of welfare.

This paper will, however, focus on the social democratic and the institutional model theories as the most relevant to the British welfare system. The social democratic theory recognizes and acknowledges the presence of classes within a society. It is the varying interests of these classes which influence the politics of the day and the welfare system. This is more so true in Britain, where the politics are influenced by the interests of the labour and conservative parties.

Also, the institutional model of welfare is relevant because it asserts that the government has a major role to play in the welfare system of a state. In essence, the government is not only limited to operate in the public sphere, but it has a direct bearing on the private social lives of its citizens. This is a reflection of the goals that were set out under the Beveridge report, which provided that it is the duty of the state to ensure a minimum standard of life for all its citizens. This theory is therefore indicative of the system of welfare in Britain because it informs the decision of the state to interfere in the lives of its citizens to ensure that all of them achieve a quality of life that does not fall below a certain minimum requirement.

The Impact of the British Welfare System on Class Inequalities

The main inequalities in society are those that relate to disparities in income and wealth, gender, and race (Spicker 2014). All welfare is usually redistributive in the sense that the people that receive the benefits of welfare are not normally the ones that pay for them. Recently, the welfare system has fallen out of favour with the British public. But the negative review of the system is not only recent but has subsisted for a long time (Baumberg 2012).

Some authors assert that the British welfare system failed to address the class inequality problem because that was not the intention of its adoption in the first place (History in Focus, n.d.). Their argument is that the social welfare system was premised on the assumption that all the citizens would be employed, and all those that could work as a result of sickness or retirement or any other legitimate reason would receive a basic, minimum income.

Moreover, the welfare system has significantly reduced the gap between the highest and the lowest income even though it has not succeeded in bridging the gap between the rich and the have-nots (History in Focus, n.d). Other authors assert that the welfare system has failed in that some people have benefited very little from it while others argue that the inequalities have been made worse and more deeply entrenched (Calder & Gass 2012).

Part of the reason why the welfare system has failed to eliminate disparities is because of the general perception that the public has of it. Statistics show that 66% of Britons believe that the welfare system makes the recipients lazy (Baumberg 2012). This therefore goes to show that those that contribute towards the maintenance of the system may be jaundiced against those that are receiving its benefits. Furthermore, if this belief is true, then the income inequality can never be done away with because those that receive the welfare will never have the impetus to bridge the gap.

From the above discussion, it is evident that the British welfare system may not have ultimately achieved the purpose for which it was set up. However, this assertion is only true depending on the angle from which you view it. If its purpose was to bridge inequality, then it may be regarded as having failed, but as has been shown, some critics state that it has not failed at all because the intention of the welfare system was not to eradicate inequality but rather, to secure a minimum standard of life for every citizen.

Health Inequalities

Health inequalities are taken to mean the unjustifiable differences in health between the different groups that make up a society. Various theories attempt to explain health disparities. They include (Socialist Health Association 1980):

Artefact theory

Here, both health and class are treated as artefacts in the measurement process. The theory goes further to explain that the manner in which these inequalities present themselves in the 20 th century may be a mirror of the changes in the structure of occupations in Britain and not of the connection between economic stability and health. The new entrants in the labour force will more often than not opt for the new job opportunities and therefore it may be that those who account for ill health are the people that choose to remain in trades that have poor medical records.

Natural and Social Selection theory

In this theory, the structure of occupational classes is viewed as some filter that selects people by health i.e., agility, physical strength, and vigour. The Register General’s class I is, therefore, considered to record the least numbers of premature death because it has the most physically fit while class V consists of the poorest in health. Mostly, poor health also carries a poor economic reward. It is, therefore, used to explain why people with diseases often live very short lives.

Materialist or Structural Theory

This uses economic and other social considerations to account for the distribution of standards of well-being in the society. This theory focuses on the direct influence that different poverty levels have on the varying rates of mortality. It leads to the question of whether the materially endowed have managed to maintain their health at the expense of the economically deprived.

In Britain, research shows that it is the poorest people who suffer the worst health. The reason for this has been posited to be the fact that there also exists a wide disparity in socioeconomic conditions between the various groups in the society (Pickett & Wilkinson 2013).

Furthermore, it has been argued that this gulf is only widening in the last thirty years, despite the existence of the social welfare system. Ideally, the argument is that those who are wealthy, powerful and economically stable can protect their health while the poorer percentage of the society cannot. The assumption, therefore, is that the only way that the social gradient in health will be reduced is by also reducing the difference in income and wealth.

The Register General’s Social Classes were introduced in 1913, and consisted of five classes as follows:

  • Professional Occupations.
  • Managerial and Technical Occupations.
  • Skilled and Non-manual occupations.
  • Skilled manual occupations.
  • Unskilled occupations.

The theories explained above, therefore, aim to explain the health inequalities between the members of class I and those of class V. These two categories represent the two ends of the spectrum and are therefore most appropriate to describe those who are economically stable and those who are not respectively. Extrapolating from these findings the situation in Britain is, therefore, such that the economic disparity between these two classes is increasing thus leading to a proportionate increase in health inequalities.

It is evident from the above research that the social welfare system in Britain has been of great importance as it has influenced every sphere of life since its inception in the 15 th century. The introduction of social welfare was a landmark in the history of Britain as it marked the government’s decision to move beyond the public sphere to regulate the private lives of its citizens. Furthermore, this paper has also shown that the social welfare system has played a critical role in the politics of the country and still continues to do so.

However, some concerning findings include the fact that despite the welfare system which has been in place for a long time, the inequalities in Britain only continue to increase. This is more so in the economic and income sectors, and the direct result of these variations is disparities in the standards of health between the different groups that form the British Society. The conclusion that can be drawn, therefore, is that the social welfare system has failed to solve the inequality problem in Britain, and it will take a new strategy or the adoption of different policies if this issue is to be solved.

Baumberg, B 2012, ‘ The positive and the negative consequences of the welfare state ’, Inequalities. Web.

Calder, G & Gass, J 2012, Changing directions of the British welfare state, University of Wales Press, Wales.

Englander, D 2013, Poverty and poor law reform in nineteenth-century Britain, 1834-1914: From Chadwick to Booth, Routledge, New York, NY.

Hansan, JE 2011, English poor laws: Historical precedents of tax-supported relief for the poor . Web.

Harris, NS 2000, Social security law in context, Oxford University Press, New York, NY.

History in Focus. n.d., Why did the post war welfare state fail to prevent the growth of inequality . Web.

Mau, S & Veghte, B 2007, Social justice, legitimacy and the welfare state, Ashgate Publishing, Hampshire.

Picket, K & Wilkinson, R 2013, ‘Health inequality is blighting the UK’, Independent. Web.

Roos, JP 1973. Welfare theory and social policy: a study in policy science, Roos Helsinki, Japan.

Rowntree, S n.d., ‘Poverty and reform’, Bitesize. Web.

Socialist Health Association. 1980, Black report 6 explanation of health inequalities . Web.

Spicker, P 2014, Social policy: Theory and practice, Policy Press, New York, NY.

The National Archives. n.d., The welfare state . Web.

  • Ross Matsueda: Specifying a Symbolic Interactionist Theory
  • Diffusion Innovation Theory and People Categories
  • Gender Identity: Modernity and the Witch Hunts
  • Importance of the Social Model of Disability
  • The Nature of Addiction
  • Capitalism in Marx's, Weber's, Durkheim's Theories
  • Time Management: How to Beat Your Procrastination?
  • Durkheim's Ideas on Social Solidarity
  • Positivism and Subjectivity in Sociology
  • Social Exchange Theory and Human Relationships
  • Chicago (A-D)
  • Chicago (N-B)

IvyPanda. (2020, September 22). The British Welfare System. https://ivypanda.com/essays/the-british-welfare-system/

"The British Welfare System." IvyPanda , 22 Sept. 2020, ivypanda.com/essays/the-british-welfare-system/.

IvyPanda . (2020) 'The British Welfare System'. 22 September.

IvyPanda . 2020. "The British Welfare System." September 22, 2020. https://ivypanda.com/essays/the-british-welfare-system/.

1. IvyPanda . "The British Welfare System." September 22, 2020. https://ivypanda.com/essays/the-british-welfare-system/.

Bibliography

IvyPanda . "The British Welfare System." September 22, 2020. https://ivypanda.com/essays/the-british-welfare-system/.

  • Search Search Please fill out this field.

What Is a Social Welfare System?

  • How It Works

The Bottom Line

  • Government & Policy

Social Welfare System: Definition and How It Works

Julia Kagan is a financial/consumer journalist and former senior editor, personal finance, of Investopedia.

essay on welfare system

A social welfare system refers to a broad network of programs, subsidies, and supports available to provide financial and material assistance to individuals and families in need.

The types and amount of welfare available to individuals and families vary depending on the country, state, or region. Eligibility for benefits typically also depends on income and assets.

Key Takeaways

  • A social welfare system offers assistance to individuals and families in need, with such programs as health care assistance, food stamps, and unemployment compensation. 
  • Lesser known parts of a social welfare system include disaster relief and educational assistance.
  • Eligibility for benefits is based on a number of factors, including income levels and family size.

How a Social Welfare System Works

Social welfare systems provide assistance to individuals and families through programs such as health care, food stamps, unemployment compensation , housing assistance, and child care assistance. In the U.S., a caseworker is assigned to each individual or family applying for benefits to determine and confirm the applicant's needs.

The benefits available to an individual vary by state. Eligibility is determined based on factors surrounding the person’s financial status and how it relates to the minimum acceptable levels within a particular state. The factors involved can include the size of the family unit, current income levels, or an assessed disability.

The benefits that an individual or family receives as part of a social welfare system will vary by state, as will the eligibility requirements. 

Within each state, social welfare systems may go by different names, but they often serve similar functions. This can cause confusion when attempting to compare one state's program to another. Additionally, the requirements to qualify also vary, depending on the poverty line in a particular state. This allows for adjustments based on items such as cost of living that are not standardized across the country.

Benefits of Social Welfare Systems

Available benefits generally cover assistance for food, housing, child care, and medical care.

Some available housing benefits go beyond locating suitable and affordable properties and providing housing cost assistance. A household may qualify for assistance to complete certain energy efficiency upgrades. It may also receive funds to help pay utility bills.

Benefits around health and nutrition can include access to affordable medical care. Food and nutrition programs may supply funds, often referred to as food stamps or the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (SNAP), to provide easier access to food in general . Additional nutritional assistance through the Women, Infants and Children (WIC) program provides food-specific benefits to ensure pregnant women and young children have access to healthy food options to promote growth and development.

Other programs that are part of the social welfare system include disaster relief assistance, educational assistance, agricultural loans, and services specifically for veterans.

The federal government also provides block grants to each state through the Temporary Assistance for Needy Families (TANF) program. TANF funds are provided to the states for distribution. These funds may be used for cash assistance, allowing a household to spend the funds as it deems necessary to meet its needs and obligations.

What Are Examples of Social Welfare?

In the U.S., there are numerous government programs that together make up the social welfare system. At the federal level, programs include SNAP, which provides monthly payments to support the purchase of food, and Medicaid , which provides low-income families with health insurance. At the state level, resources vary but include the likes of energy subsidies, cash assistance, housing vouchers, and job training programs.

What Is Another Word for Social Welfare?

Other terms used to refer to social welfare include public assistance, public benefits, and the social safety net.

What Is the Problem with Social Welfare?

Social welfare programs are generally welcomed by policymakers and constituents, who say that they provide a safety net for unexpected circumstances like job loss and poverty . However, social welfare has also drawn criticism. Common arguments against social welfare include the idea of welfare dependence, a state in which an individual relies heavily on public benefits programs without contributing to them. Other criticisms include potential high costs to taxpayers and potential inflationary risks of large-scale welfare spending.

A social welfare system provides assistance to individuals and families in need. Social welfare systems vary by region but typically may include nutrition support, cash assistance, housing support, and vocational training. To qualify for social welfare, programs typically impose income and wealth-based eligibility criteria.

Benefits.gov. " Weatherization Assistance Program for Low-Income Persons ." Accessed Sept. 29, 2020.

Benefits.gov. " Low Income Home Energy Assistance Progra (LIHEAP) ." Accessed Sept. 29, 2020.

Benefits.gov. " Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (SNAP) ." Accessed Sept. 29, 2020.

Benefits.gov. " Special Supplemental Nutrition Program for Women, Infants and Children (WIC) ." Accessed Sept. 29, 2020.

Benefits.gov. " Temporary Assistance for Needy Families ." Accessed Sept. 29, 2020.

essay on welfare system

  • Terms of Service
  • Editorial Policy
  • Privacy Policy

Social Welfare System Essays

Social welfare approach, popular essay topics.

  • American Dream
  • Artificial Intelligence
  • Black Lives Matter
  • Bullying Essay
  • Career Goals Essay
  • Causes of the Civil War
  • Child Abusing
  • Civil Rights Movement
  • Community Service
  • Cultural Identity
  • Cyber Bullying
  • Death Penalty
  • Depression Essay
  • Domestic Violence
  • Freedom of Speech
  • Global Warming
  • Gun Control
  • Human Trafficking
  • I Believe Essay
  • Immigration
  • Importance of Education
  • Israel and Palestine Conflict
  • Leadership Essay
  • Legalizing Marijuanas
  • Mental Health
  • National Honor Society
  • Police Brutality
  • Pollution Essay
  • Racism Essay
  • Romeo and Juliet
  • Same Sex Marriages
  • Social Media
  • The Great Gatsby
  • The Yellow Wallpaper
  • Time Management
  • To Kill a Mockingbird
  • Violent Video Games
  • What Makes You Unique
  • Why I Want to Be a Nurse
  • Send us an e-mail

IMAGES

  1. US Welfare System Essay Example

    essay on welfare system

  2. Social Welfare Systems Definition

    essay on welfare system

  3. The British Welfare System

    essay on welfare system

  4. Science and Human Welfare

    essay on welfare system

  5. The Welfare System

    essay on welfare system

  6. Comparative Review of Welfare System Term Paper

    essay on welfare system

VIDEO

  1. Welfare state / features / important and criticism (Political science)

  2. social welfare administration-meaning, concept and nature in social work I Hindi

  3. PMS: Social Work Lecture-11 Paper-2 ll Social Welfare Administration

  4. What is the meaning of welfare state

  5. Personal Responsibilities of Nurses and Their Extension

  6. Checking vs. Savings Account

COMMENTS

  1. The Welfare System

    A welfare system is a term used to indicate government programs created in order to offer support to the needy citizens. Various types of welfare programs that have been created for this purpose include social security, financial aid, corporate welfare, and welfare provisions (Powell & Hendricks 24). Get a custom essay on The Welfare System.

  2. United States Welfare System Argumentative Essay Examples

    Read Sample United States Welfare System Argumentative Essays and other exceptional papers on every subject and topic college can throw at you. We can custom-write anything as well!

  3. The Shortcomings of a Work-Biased Welfare System

    The Shortcomings of a Work-Biased Welfare System. The recently passed American Rescue Plan Act has once again brought attention to the U.S. welfare system. This EB provides an overview of the welfare system — including recent changes — and assesses the system's effectiveness in achieving its goals. The brief highlights a "work bias" that is ...

  4. The U.S. Welfare System Essay

    The welfare system has changed over the year from a long-term to short-term assistance in order to encourage independency. Not only does the tax funded welfare programs provide a means of distributing the wealth across the country, but also control poverty in America and improve the standard of living for low-income families.

  5. Welfare Essay

    Welfare comes in all different shapes and sizes but its main focus is to take money from taxes and hand it out to the people who need it. Now welfare as a whole is a very understandable system and is very helpful to those who fall out of work and need a little help to sustain themselves while they get back on. 1360 Words.

  6. Social Welfare Essay

    The social welfare system in the United States is defined through several different sectors of government and generally comes along with a negative stigma. When people hear about social welfare they generally tend to think about the government assistance programs, and not the other programs such as tax credits or "social insurance" (Tussing ...

  7. Development, Welfare Policy, and the Welfare State

    In contrast to the period until the mid-1980s that focused on welfare state expansion, the late 1980s saw the emergence of new streams of literature whose emphasis was on welfare state retrenchment.

  8. Argumentative Essay On The Welfare System

    Argumentative Essay On The Welfare System. 586 Words 3 Pages. With 21% of the United States population assisted by welfare in 2016 ("Welfare Statistics"), one could imagine the strong demand and impact of the welfare system. One out of every five people you pass on the street receive aid from the United States welfare system.

  9. The Social Welfare System, Essay Example

    Essays.io ️ The Social Welfare System, Essay Example from students accepted to Harvard, Stanford, and other elite schools

  10. The British Welfare System

    The social welfare system in Britain has been of great importance as it has influenced every sphere of life since its inception in the 15th century.

  11. Social Welfare System: Definition and How It Works

    A social welfare system is a government program that provides assistance to individuals and families in need.

  12. American Welfare System Essay

    American Welfare System Essay 740 Words3 Pages The American Welfare System Many people have different opinions on the way our government is run. Welfare programs are something not a lot of people agree with. Some see it as a helping hand and others see it as a handout to people who are too lazy to get a job.

  13. Welfare Of The Welfare System

    Free Essay: Welfare Abuse in America The welfare systems are based on the principle of public responsibility on equitable wealth distribution and equality of...

  14. Social Welfare System Essay Examples

    Social welfare is an area of public policy concerned with the welfare of individuals and families. The social welfare approach is based on the belief that individuals and families are the best people to make decisions about their own lives and that the government should help them.

  15. UKnowledge- University of Kentucky Libraries

    UKnowledge- University of Kentucky Libraries

  16. Welfare Essays: Examples, Topics, & Outlines

    View our collection of welfare essays. Find inspiration for topics, titles, outlines, & craft impactful welfare papers. Read our welfare papers today!

  17. Welfare System

    Download this essay on Welfare System and 90,000+ more example essays written by professionals and your peers.

  18. Abuse Of The Welfare System Essay

    Research-Based Toulmin Argument Paper On Welfare 907 Words | 4 Pages Research-Based Toulmin Argument Paper The term "welfare" is one that is used too loosely and without the proper knowledge in our society. "Eligibility for participation in government benefit programs can be based either on financial need or the occurrence of an event, such as reaching retirement age" (Kessler, 2015, p ...

  19. Persuasive Essay On The Welfare System

    The Welfare system was established during the Great Depression in "1935, by Franklin D. Roosevelt, after signing the Social Security Act" (CRF). This was made to help the citizens during the depression who couldn't provide for their retirement fund, homes and more.

  20. How the Child-Welfare System Could Protect More Kids and Save Billions

    America's child-welfare system could save billions of dollars while helping more families and protecting more children from abuse and neglect, a recent RAND study concluded. The study provides a first-of-its-kind look at how the system works, and how it could work better. It found that a greater emphasis on preventing maltreatment before it ...

  21. Welfare System In America Essay

    The most notorious welfare fraud case occurred in Chicago in the 1970's. A woman named Linda Taylor defrauded the government out of $150,000 annually by using eighty different names, thirty addresses and fifteen phone numbers. She collected food stamps, social security and veteran's benefits from four nonexistent deceased veteran husbands.

  22. United States Welfare System Essay

    A welfare system is nowhere near simple in any fashion. Today's systems work upon market forces, government programs and of course the people. The United States welfare state is one of controversy unlike any other. The traditional view, for the most part, is negative because the United States welfare system lags behind in implementing successful policies that benefit all. As well as the ...

  23. Essay On The Welfare System

    Essay On The Welfare System. The welfare system we have in the U.S. is flawed in so many ways that we need to change it. The welfare system is failing by letting people buy drugs with their money, let's people take the money without a reason for it, and letting the government have all the power. If we really want the welfare system to become ...