Logo for Open Library Publishing Platform

Want to create or adapt books like this? Learn more about how Pressbooks supports open publishing practices.

8.8 Hypothesis Tests for a Population Proportion

Learning objectives.

  • Conduct and interpret hypothesis tests for a population proportion.

Some notes about conducting a hypothesis test:

  • The null hypothesis [latex]H_0[/latex] is always an “equal to.”  The null hypothesis is the original claim about the population parameter.
  • The alternative hypothesis [latex]H_a[/latex] is a “less than,” “greater than,” or “not equal to.”  The form of the alternative hypothesis depends on the context of the question.
  • If the alternative hypothesis is a “less than”, then the test is left-tail.  The p -value is the area in the left-tail of the distribution.
  • If the alternative hypothesis is a “greater than”, then the test is right-tail.  The p -value is the area in the right-tail of the distribution.
  • If the alternative hypothesis is a “not equal to”, then the test is two-tail.  The p -value is the sum of the area in the two-tails of the distribution.  Each tail represents exactly half of the p -value.
  • Think about the meaning of the p -value.  A data analyst (and anyone else) should have more confidence that they made the correct decision to reject the null hypothesis with a smaller p -value (for example, 0.001 as opposed to 0.04) even if using a significance level of 0.05. Similarly, for a large p -value such as 0.4, as opposed to a p -value of 0.056 (a significance level of 0.05 is less than either number), a data analyst should have more confidence that they made the correct decision in not rejecting the null hypothesis. This makes the data analyst use judgment rather than mindlessly applying rules.
  • The significance level must be identified before collecting the sample data and conducting the test.  Generally, the significance level will be included in the question.  If no significance level is given, a common standard is to use a significance level of 5%.

Suppose the hypotheses for a hypothesis test are:

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} H_0: & & p=20 \% \\ H_a: & & p \gt 20\% \end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

Because the alternative hypothesis is a [latex]\gt[/latex], this is a right-tail test.  The p -value is the area in the right-tail of the distribution.

Normal distribution curve of a single population proportion with the value of 0.2 on the x-axis. The p-value points to the area on the right tail of the curve.

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} H_0: & & p=50 \% \\ H_a: & & p \neq  50\% \end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

Because the alternative hypothesis is a [latex]\neq[/latex], this is a two-tail test.  The p -value is the sum of the areas in the two tails of the distribution.  Each tail contains exactly half of the p -value.

Normal distribution curve of a single population mean with a value of 50 on the x-axis. The p-value formulas, 1/2(p-value), for a two-tailed test is shown for the areas on the left and right tails of the curve.

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} H_0: & & p=10\% \\ H_a: & & p \lt  10\% \end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

Because the alternative hypothesis is a [latex]\lt[/latex], this is a left-tail test.  The p -value is the area in the left-tail of the distribution.

Steps to Conduct a Hypothesis Test for a Population Proportion

  • Write down the null and alternative hypotheses in terms of the population proportion [latex]p[/latex].  Include appropriate units with the values of the proportion.
  • Use the form of the alternative hypothesis to determine if the test is left-tailed, right-tailed, or two-tailed.
  • Collect the sample information for the test and identify the significance level.
  • If [latex]n \times p \geq 5[/latex] and [latex]n \times (1-p) \geq 5[/latex], use the normal distribution with [latex]\displaystyle{z=\frac{\hat{p}-p}{\sqrt{\frac{p \times (1-p)}{n}}}}[/latex].
  • If one of [latex]n \times p \lt 5[/latex] or [latex]n \times (1-p) \lt 5[/latex], use a binomial distribution.
  • The results of the sample data are significant.  There is sufficient evidence to conclude that the null hypothesis [latex]H_0[/latex] is an incorrect belief and that the alternative hypothesis [latex]H_a[/latex] is most likely correct.
  • The results of the sample data are not significant.  There is not sufficient evidence to conclude that the alternative hypothesis [latex]H_a[/latex] may be correct.
  • Write down a concluding sentence specific to the context of the question.

USING EXCEL TO CALCULE THE P -VALUE FOR A HYPOTHESIS TEST ON A POPULATION PROPORTION

The p -value for a hypothesis test on a population proportion is the area in the tail(s) of distribution of the sample proportion.  If both [latex]n \times p \geq 5[/latex] and [latex]n \times (1-p) \geq 5[/latex], use the normal distribution to find the p -value.  If at least one of [latex]n \times p \lt 5[/latex] or [latex]n \times (1-p) \lt 5[/latex], use the binomial distribution to find the p -value.

If both [latex]n \times p \geq 5[/latex] and [latex]n \times (1-p) \geq 5[/latex]:

  • For x , enter the value for [latex]\hat{p}[/latex].
  • For [latex]\mu[/latex] , enter the mean of the sample proportions [latex]p[/latex].  Note:  Because the test is run assuming the null hypothesis is true, the value for [latex]p[/latex] is the claim from the null hypothesis.
  • For [latex]\sigma[/latex] , enter the standard error of the proportions [latex]\displaystyle{\sqrt{\frac{p \times (1-p)}{n}}}[/latex].
  • For the logic operator , enter true .  Note:  Because we are calculating the area under the curve, we always enter true for the logic operator.
  • Use the appropriate technique with the norm.dist function to find the area in the left-tail or the area in the right-tail.

If at least one of [latex]n \times p \lt 5[/latex] or [latex]n \times (1-p) \lt 5[/latex]:

  • The p -value is found using the binomial distribution.
  • For x , enter the number of successes.
  • For n , enter the sample size.
  • For p , enter the the value of the population proportion [latex]p[/latex] from the null hypothesis.
  • For the logic operator , enter true .  Note:  Because we are calculating an at most probability, the logic operator is always true.
  • For p , enter the the value of the population proportion [latex]p[/latex] in the null hypothesis.
  • For the logic operator , enter true .  Note:  Because we are calculating an at least probability, the logic operator is always true.

Marketers believe that 92% of adults own a cell phone.  A cell phone manufacturer believes that number is actually lower.  In a sample of 200 adults, 87% own a cell phone.  At the 1% significance level, determine if the proportion of adults that own a cell phone is lower than the marketers’ claim.

Hypotheses:

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} H_0: & & p=92\% \mbox{ of adults own a cell phone} \\ H_a: & & p \lt 92\% \mbox{ of adults own a cell phone} \end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

From the question, we have [latex]n=200[/latex], [latex]\hat{p}=0.87[/latex], and [latex]\alpha=0.01[/latex].

To determine the distribution, we check [latex]n \times p[/latex] and [latex]n \times (1-p)[/latex].  For the value of [latex]p[/latex], we use the claim from the null hypothesis ([latex]p=0.92[/latex]).

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} n \times p & = & 200 \times 0.92=184 \geq 5 \\ n \times (1-p) & = & 200 \times (1-0.92)=16 \geq 5\end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

Because both [latex]n \times p \geq 5[/latex] and [latex]n \times (1-p)  \geq 5[/latex] we use a normal distribution to calculate the p -value.  Because the alternative hypothesis is a [latex]\lt[/latex], the p -value is the area in the left tail of the distribution.

This is a normal distribution curve. On the left side of the center a vertical line extends to the curve with the area to the left of this vertical line shaded. The p-value equals the area of this shaded region.

norm.dist
0.87 0.0046
0.92
sqrt(0.92*(1-0.92)/200)
true

So the p -value[latex]=0.0046[/latex].

Conclusion:

Because p -value[latex]=0.0046 \lt 0.01=\alpha[/latex], we reject the null hypothesis in favour of the alternative hypothesis.  At the 1% significance level there is enough evidence to suggest that the proportion of adults who own a cell phone is lower than 92%.

  • The null hypothesis [latex]p=92\%[/latex] is the claim that 92% of adults own a cell phone.
  • The alternative hypothesis [latex]p \lt 92\%[/latex] is the claim that less than 92% of adults own a cell phone.
  • The function is norm.dist because we are finding the area in the left tail of a normal distribution.
  • Field 1 is the value of [latex]\hat{p}[/latex].
  • Field 2 is the value of [latex]p[/latex] from the null hypothesis.  Remember, we run the test assuming the null hypothesis is true, so that means we assume [latex]p=0.92[/latex].
  • Field 3 is the standard deviation for the sample proportions [latex]\displaystyle{\sqrt{\frac{p \times (1-p)}{n}}}[/latex].
  • The p -value of 0.0046 tells us that under the assumption that 92% of adults own a cell phone (the null hypothesis), there is only a 0.46% chance that the proportion of adults who own a cell phone in a sample of 200 is 87% or less.  This is a small probability, and so is unlikely to happen assuming the null hypothesis is true.  This suggests that the assumption that the null hypothesis is true is most likely incorrect, and so the conclusion of the test is to reject the null hypothesis in favour of the alternative hypothesis.  In other words, the proportion of adults who own a cell phone is most likely less than 92%.

A consumer group claims that the proportion of households that have at least three cell phones is 30%.  A cell phone company has reason to believe that the proportion of households with at least three cell phones is much higher.  Before they start a big advertising campaign based on the proportion of households that have at least three cell phones, they want to test their claim.  Their marketing people survey 150 households with the result that 54 of the households have at least three cell phones.  At the 1% significance level, determine if the proportion of households that have at least three cell phones is less than 30%.

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} H_0: & & p=30\% \mbox{ of household have at least 3 cell phones} \\ H_a: & & p \gt 30\% \mbox{ of household have at least 3 cell phones} \end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

From the question, we have [latex]n=150[/latex], [latex]\displaystyle{\hat{p}=\frac{54}{150}=0.36}[/latex], and [latex]\alpha=0.01[/latex].

To determine the distribution, we check [latex]n \times p[/latex] and [latex]n \times (1-p)[/latex].  For the value of [latex]p[/latex], we use the claim from the null hypothesis ([latex]p=0.3[/latex]).

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} n \times p & = & 150 \times 0.3=45 \geq 5 \\ n \times (1-p) & = & 150 \times (1-0.3)=105 \geq 5\end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

Because both [latex]n \times p \geq 5[/latex] and [latex]n \times (1-p)  \geq  5[/latex] we use a normal distribution to calculate the p -value.  Because the alternative hypothesis is a [latex]\gt[/latex], the p -value is the area in the right tail of the distribution.

This is a normal distribution curve. On the right side of the center a vertical line extends to the curve with the area to the right of this vertical line shaded. The p-value equals the area of this shaded region.

1-norm.dist
0.36 0.0544
0.3
sqrt(0.3*(1-0.3)/150)
true

So the p -value[latex]=0.0544[/latex].

Because p -value[latex]=0.0544 \gt 0.01=\alpha[/latex], we do not reject the null hypothesis.  At the 1% significance level there is not enough evidence to suggest that the proportion of households with at least three cell phones is more than 30%.

  • The null hypothesis [latex]p=30\%[/latex] is the claim that 30% of households have at least three cell phones.
  • The alternative hypothesis [latex]p \gt 30\%[/latex] is the claim that more than 30% of households have at least three cell phones.
  • The function is 1-norm.dist because we are finding the area in the right tail of a normal distribution.
  • Field 2 is the value of [latex]p[/latex] from the null hypothesis.  Remember, we run the test assuming the null hypothesis is true, so that means we assume [latex]p=0.3[/latex].
  • The p -value of 0.0544 tells us that under the assumption that 30% of households have at least three cell phones (the null hypothesis), there is a 5.44% chance that the proportion of households with at least three cell phones in a sample of 150 is 36% or more.  Compared to the 1% significance level, this is a large probability, and so is likely to happen assuming the null hypothesis is true.  This suggests that the assumption that the null hypothesis is true is most likely correct, and so the conclusion of the test is to not reject the null hypothesis.  In other words, the claim that 30% of households have at least three cell phones is most likely correct.

A teacher believes that 70% of students in the class will want to go on a field trip to the local zoo.  The students in the class believe the proportion is much higher and ask the teacher to verify her claim.  The teacher samples 50 students and 39 reply that they would want to go to the zoo.  At the 5% significance level, determine if the proportion of students who want to go on the field trip is higher than 70%.

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} H_0: & & p = 70\% \mbox{ of students want to go on the field trip}  \\ H_a: & & p \gt 70\% \mbox{ of students want to go on the field trip}   \end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

From the question, we have [latex]n=50[/latex], [latex]\displaystyle{\hat{p}=\frac{39}{50}=0.78}[/latex], and [latex]\alpha=0.05[/latex].

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} n \times p & = & 50 \times 0.7=35 \geq 5 \\ n \times (1-p) & = & 50 \times (1-0.7)=15 \geq 5\end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

Because both [latex]n \times p \geq 5[/latex] and [latex]n \times (1-p)  \geq 5[/latex] we use a normal distribution to calculate the p -value.  Because the alternative hypothesis is a [latex]\gt[/latex], the p -value is the area in the right tail of the distribution.

1-norm.dist
0.78 0.1085
0.7
sqrt(0.7*(1-0.7)/50)
true

So the p -value[latex]=0.1085[/latex].

Because p -value[latex]=0.1085 \gt 0.05=\alpha[/latex], we do not reject the null hypothesis.  At the 5% significance level there is not enough evidence to suggest that the proportion of students who want to go on the field trip is higher than 70%.

  • The null hypothesis [latex]p=70\%[/latex] is the claim that 70% of the students want to go on the field trip.
  • The alternative hypothesis [latex]p \gt 70\%[/latex] is the claim that more than 70% of students want to go on the field trip.
  • The p -value of 0.1085 tells us that under the assumption that 70% of students want to go on the field trip (the null hypothesis), there is a 10.85% chance that the proportion of students who want to go on the field trip in a sample of 50 students is 78% or more.  Compared to the 5% significance level, this is a large probability, and so is likely to happen assuming the null hypothesis is true.  This suggests that the assumption that the null hypothesis is true is most likely correct, and so the conclusion of the test is to not reject the null hypothesis.  In other words, the teacher’s claim that 70% of students want to go on the field trip is most likely correct.

Joan believes that 50% of first-time brides in the United States are younger than their grooms.  She performs a hypothesis test to determine if the percentage is the same or different from 50%.  Joan samples 100 first-time brides and 56 reply that they are younger than their grooms.  Use a 5% significance level.

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} H_0: & & p=50\% \mbox{ of first-time brides are younger than the groom} \\ H_a: & & p \neq 50\% \mbox{ of first-time brides are younger than the groom} \end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

From the question, we have [latex]n=100[/latex], [latex]\displaystyle{\hat{p}=\frac{56}{100}=0.56}[/latex], and [latex]\alpha=0.05[/latex].

To determine the distribution, we check [latex]n \times p[/latex] and [latex]n \times (1-p)[/latex].  For the value of [latex]p[/latex], we use the claim from the null hypothesis ([latex]p=0.5[/latex]).

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} n \times p & = & 100 \times 0.5=50 \geq 5 \\ n \times (1-p) & = & 100 \times (1-0.5)=50 \geq 5\end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

Because both [latex]n \times p \geq 5[/latex] and [latex]n \times (1-p)  \geq 5[/latex] we use a normal distribution to calculate the p -value.  Because the alternative hypothesis is a [latex]\neq[/latex], the p -value is the sum of area in the tails of the distribution.

This is a normal distribution curve. On the left side of the center a vertical line extends to the curve with the area to the left of this vertical line shaded and labeled as one half of the p-value. On the right side of the center a vertical line extends to the curve with the area to the right of this vertical line shaded and labeled as one half of the p-value. The p-value equals the sum of area of these two shaded regions.

Because there is only one sample, we only have information relating to one of the two tails, either the left or the right.  We need to know if the sample relates to the left or right tail because that will determine how we calculate out the area of that tail using the normal distribution.  In this case, the sample proportion [latex]\hat{p}=0.56[/latex] is greater than the value of the population proportion in the null hypothesis [latex]p=0.5[/latex] ([latex]\hat{p}=0.56>0.5=p[/latex]), so the sample information relates to the right-tail of the normal distribution.  This means that we will calculate out the area in the right tail using 1-norm.dist .  However, this is a two-tailed test where the p -value is the sum of the area in the two tails and the area in the right-tail is only one half of the p -value.  The area in the left tail equals the area in the right tail and the p -value is the sum of these two areas.

1-norm.dist
0.56 0.1151
0.5
sqrt(0.5*(1-0.5)/100)
true

So the area in the right tail is 0.1151 and  [latex]\frac{1}{2}[/latex]( p -value)[latex]=0.1151[/latex].  This is also the area in the left tail, so

p -value[latex]=0.1151+0.1151=0.2302[/latex]

Because p -value[latex]=0.2302 \gt 0.05=\alpha[/latex], we do not reject the null hypothesis.  At the 5% significance level there is not enough evidence to suggest that the proportion of first-time brides that are younger than the groom is different from 50%.

  • The null hypothesis [latex]p=50\%[/latex] is the claim that the proportion of first-time brides that are younger than the groom is 50%.
  • The alternative hypothesis [latex]p \neq 50\%[/latex] is the claim that the proportion of first-time brides that are younger than the groom is different from 50%.
  • We use norm.dist([latex]\hat{p}[/latex],[latex]p[/latex],[latex]\mbox{sqrt}(p*(1-p)/n)[/latex],true) to find the area in the left tail.  The area in the right tail equals the area in the left tail, so we can find the p -value by adding the output from this function to itself.
  • We use 1-norm.dist([latex]\hat{p}[/latex],[latex]p[/latex],[latex]\mbox{sqrt}(p*(1-p)/n)[/latex],true) to find the area in the right tail.  The area in the left tail equals the area in the right tail, so we can find the p -value by adding the output from this function to itself.
  • The p -value of 0.2302  is a large probability compared to the 5% significance level, and so is likely to happen assuming the null hypothesis is true.  This suggests that the assumption that the null hypothesis is true is most likely correct, and so the conclusion of the test is to not reject the null hypothesis.  In other words, the claim that the proportion of first-time brides who are younger than the groom is most likely correct.

Watch this video: Hypothesis Testing for Proportions: z -test by ExcelIsFun [7:27] 

An online retailer believes that 93% of the visitors to its website will make a purchase.   A researcher in the marketing department thinks the actual percent is lower than claimed.  The researcher examines a sample of 50 visits to the website and finds that 45 of the visits resulted in a purchase.  At the 1% significance level, determine if the proportion of visits to the website that result in a purchase is lower than claimed.

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} H_0: & & p=93\% \mbox{ of visitors make a purchase} \\ H_a: & & p \lt 93\% \mbox{ of visitors make a purchase} \end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

From the question, we have [latex]n=50[/latex], [latex]x=45[/latex], and [latex]\alpha=0.01[/latex].

To determine the distribution, we check [latex]n \times p[/latex] and [latex]n \times (1-p)[/latex].  For the value of [latex]p[/latex], we use the claim from the null hypothesis ([latex]p=0.93[/latex]).

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} n \times p & = & 50 \times 0.93=46.5 \geq 5 \\ n \times (1-p) & = & 50 \times (1-0.93)=3.5 \lt 5\end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

Because [latex]n \times (1-p)  \lt 5[/latex] we use a binomial distribution to calculate the p -value.  Because the alternative hypothesis is a [latex]\lt[/latex], the p -value is the probability of getting at most 45 successes in 50 trials.

binom.dist
45 0.2710
50
0.93
true

So the p -value[latex]=0.2710[/latex].

Because p -value[latex]=0.2710 \gt 0.01=\alpha[/latex], we do not reject the null hypothesis.  At the 1% significance level there is not enough evidence to suggest that the proportion of visitors who make a purchase is lower than 93%.

  • The null hypothesis [latex]p=93\%[/latex] is the claim that 93% of visitors to the website make a purchase.
  • The alternative hypothesis [latex]p \lt 93\%[/latex] is the claim that less than 93% of visitors to the website make a purchase.
  • The function is binom.dist because we are finding the probability of at most 45 successes.
  • Field 1 is the number of successes [latex]x[/latex].
  • Field 2 is the sample size [latex]n[/latex].
  • Field 3 is the probability of success [latex]p[/latex].  This is the claim about the population proportion made in the null hypothesis, so that means we assume [latex]p=0.93[/latex].
  • The p -value of 0.2710 tells us that under the assumption that 93% of visitors make a purchase (the null hypothesis), there is a 27.10% chance that the number of visitors in a sample of 50 who make a purchase is 45 or less.  This is a large probability compared to the significance level, and so is likely to happen assuming the null hypothesis is true.  This suggests that the assumption that the null hypothesis is true is most likely correct, and so the conclusion of the test is to not reject the null hypothesis.  In other words, the proportion of visitors to the website who make a purchase adults is most likely 93%.

A drug company claims that only 4% of people who take their new drug experience any side effects from the drug.  A researcher believes that the percent is higher than drug company’s claim.  The researcher takes a sample of 80 people who take the drug and finds that 10% of the people in the sample experience side effects from the drug.  At the 5% significance level, determine if the proportion of people who experience side effects from taking the drug is higher than claimed.

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} H_0: & & p=4\% \mbox{ of people experience side effects} \\ H_a: & & p \gt 4\% \mbox{ of people experience side effects} \end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

From the question, we have [latex]n=80[/latex], [latex]\hat{p}=0.1[/latex], and [latex]\alpha=0.05[/latex].

To determine the distribution, we check [latex]n \times p[/latex] and [latex]n \times (1-p)[/latex].  For the value of [latex]p[/latex], we use the claim from the null hypothesis ([latex]p=0.04[/latex]).

[latex]\begin{eqnarray*} n \times p & = & 80 \times 0.04=3.2 \lt 5\end{eqnarray*}[/latex]

Because [latex]n \times p  \lt 5[/latex] we use a binomial distribution to calculate the p -value.  Because the alternative hypothesis is a [latex]\gt[/latex], the p -value is the probability of getting at least 8 successes in 80 trials.  (Note:  In the sample of size 80, 10% have the characteristic of interest, so this means that [latex]80 \times 0.1=8[/latex] people in the sample have the characteristic of interest.)

1-binom.dist
7 0.0147
80
0.04
true

So the p -value[latex]=0.0147[/latex].

Because p -value[latex]=0.0147 \lt 0.05=\alpha[/latex], we reject the null hypothesis in favour of the alternative hypothesis.  At the 5% significance level there is enough evidence to suggest that the proportion of people who experience side effects from taking the drug is higher than 4%.

  • The null hypothesis [latex]p=4\%[/latex] is the claim that 4% of the people experience side effects from taking the drug.
  • The alternative hypothesis [latex]p \gt 4\%[/latex] is the claim that more than 4% of the people experience side effects from taking the drug.
  • The function is 1-binom.dist because we are finding the probability of at least 8 successes.
  • Field 1 is [latex]x-1[/latex] where [latex]x[/latex] is the number of successes.  In this case, we are using the compliment rule to change the probability of at least 8 successes into 1 minus the probability of at most 7 successes.
  • Field 3 is the probability of success [latex]p[/latex].  This is the claim about the population proportion made in the null hypothesis, so that means we assume [latex]p=0.04[/latex].
  • The p -value of 0.0147 tells us that under the assumption that 4% of people experience side effects (the null hypothesis), there is a 1.47% chance that the number of people in a sample of 80 who experience side effects is 8 or more.  This is a small probability compared to the significance level, and so is unlikely to happen assuming the null hypothesis is true.  This suggests that the assumption that the null hypothesis is true is most likely incorrect, and so the conclusion of the test is to reject the null hypothesis in favour of the alternative hypothesis.  In other words, the proportion of people who experience side effects is most likely greater than 4%.

Concept Review

The hypothesis test for a population proportion is a well-established process:

  • Find the p -value (the area in the corresponding tail) for the test using the appropriate distribution (normal or binomial).
  • Compare the p -value to the significance level and state the outcome of the test.

Attribution

“ 9.6   Hypothesis Testing of a Single Mean and Single Proportion “ in Introductory Statistics by OpenStax  is licensed under a  Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

Introduction to Statistics Copyright © 2022 by Valerie Watts is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 4.0 International License , except where otherwise noted.

Section 10.2: Hypothesis Tests for a Population Proportion

  • 10.1 The Language of Hypothesis Testing
  • 10.2 Hypothesis Tests for a Population Proportion
  • 10.3 Hypothesis Tests for a Population Mean
  • 10.4 Hypothesis Tests for a Population Standard Deviation
  • 10.5 Putting It Together: Which Method Do I Use?

By the end of this lesson, you will be able to...

  • explain the logic of hypothesis testing
  • test hypotheses about a population proportion
  • test hypotheses about a population proportion using the binomial probability distribution

For a quick overview of this section, watch this short video summary:

The Logic of Hypothesis Testing

Once we have our null and alternative hypotheses chosen, and our sample data collected, how do we choose whether or not to reject the null hypothesis? In a nutshell, it's this:

If the observed results are unlikely assuming that the null hypothesis is true, we say the result is statistically significant , and we reject the null hypothesis. In other words, the observed results are so unusual, that our original assumption in the null hypothesis must not have been correct.

There are generally three different methods for testing hypotheses:

  • the classical approach
  • confidence intervals

Because P -values are so much more widely used, we will be focusing on this method. You will be required to include P -values for your homework and exams. We will also frequently look at both P -values and confidence intervals to make sure the two methods align.

In general, we define the P -value this way:

The P -value is the probability of observing a sample statistic as extreme or more extreme than the one observed in the sample assuming that the null hypothesis is true.

The Sample Proportion

In Section 8.2, we learned about the distribution of the sample proportion, so let's do a quick review of that now.

We also learned some information about how the sample proportion is distributed:

Sampling Distribution of

For a random sample of size n such that n≤0.05N (in other words, the sample is less than 5% of the population),

So what we do is create a test statistic based on our sample, and then use a table or technology to find the probability of what we observed. Here are the details.

Testing Claims Regarding the Population Proportion Using P -Values

In this first section, we assume we are testing some claim about the population proportion. As usual, the following two conditions must be true:

  • np(1-p)≥10, and

Step 1 : State the null and alternative hypotheses.

H : p = p
H : p ≠ p
H : p = p
H : p < p
H : p = p
H : p > p

Step 2 : Decide on a level of significance, α , depending on the seriousness of making a Type I error. ( α will often be given as part of a test or homework question, but this will not be the case in the outside world.)

Step 4 : Determine the P -value.

Step 5 : Reject the null hypothesis if the P -value is less than the level of significance, α.

Step 6 : State the conclusion.

Calculating P -Values

Right-tailed tests.

right-tailed P-value

Left-Tailed Tests

left-tailed P-value

Two-Tailed Tests

In a two-tailed test, the P -value = 2P(Z > |z o |).

two-tailed p-value

It may seem odd to multiply the probability by two, since "or more extreme" seems to imply the area in the tail only. The reason why we do multiply by two is that even though the result was on one side, we didn't know before collecting the data , on which side it would be.

The Strength of the Evidence

Since the P -value represents the probability of observing our result or more extreme, the smaller the P -value, the more unusual our observation was. Another way to look at it is this:

The smaller the P -value, the stronger the evidence supporting the alternative hypothesis. We can use the following guideline:

  • P -value < 0.01: very strong evidence supporting the alternative hypothesis
  • 0.01 ≤ P -value < 0.05: strong evidence supporting the alternative hypothesis
  • 0.05 ≤ P -value < 0.1: some evidence supporting the alternative hypothesis
  • P -value ≥ 0.1: weak to no evidence supporting the alternative hypothesis

These values are not hard lines, of course, but they can give us a general idea of the strength of the evidence.

But wait! There is an important caveat here, which was mentioned earlier in the section about The Controversy Regarding Hypothesis Testing . The problem is that it's relatively easy to get a large p-value - just get a really large sample size! So the chart above is really with the caveat " assuming equal sample sizes in comparable studies , ... "

This isn't something every statistics text will mention, nor will every instructor mention, but it's important.

According to the Elgin Community College website , approximately 56% of ECC students are female. Suppose we wonder if the same proportion is true for math courses. If we collect a sample of 200 ECC students enrolled in math courses and find that 105 of them are female, do we have enough evidence at the 10% level of significance to say that the proportion of math students who are female is different from the general population?

Note: Be sure to check that the conditions for performing the hypothesis test are met.

[ reveal answer ]

Before we begin, we need to make sure that our sample is less than 5% of the population, and that np 0 (1-p 0 )≥10.

Since there are roughly 16,000 students at ECC (source: www.elgin.edu ), our sample of 200 is clearly less than 5% of the population. Also, np 0 (1-p 0 ) = 200(0.56)(1-0.56) = 49.28 > 10

Step 1 : H 0 : p = 0.56 H 1 : p ≠ 0.56

Step 2 : α = 0.1

Step 4 : P -value = 2•P(Z < -1.00) ≈ 0.3187 (Note that this is a 2-tailed test.)

Step 5 : Since P -value > α , we do not reject H 0 .

Step 6 : There is not enough evidence at the 5% level of significance to support the claim that the proportion of students in math courses who are female is different from the general population.

Hypothesis Testing Regarding p Using StatCrunch

> > > and H , then click .

> > > and H , then click .

* To get the counts, first create a frequency table. If you have a grouping variable, use a contingency table.

Consider the excerpt shown below (also used in Example 1 , in Section 9.3) from a poll conducted by Pew Research:

Stem cell, marijuana proposals lead in Mich. poll A recent poll shows voter support leading opposition for ballot proposals to loosen Michigan's restrictions on embryonic stem cell research and allow medical use of marijuana. The EPIC-MRA poll conducted for The Detroit News and television stations WXYZ, WILX, WOOD and WJRT found 50 percent of likely Michigan voters support the stem cell proposal , 32 percent against and 18 percent undecided. The telephone poll of 602 likely Michigan voters was conducted Sept. 22 through Wednesday. It has a margin of sampling error of plus or minus 4 percentage points. (Source: Associated Press )

Suppose we wonder if the percent of Elgin Community College students who support stem cell research is different from this. If 61 of 100 randomly selected ECC students support stem cell research, is there enough evidence at the 5% level of signficance to support our claim?

Since there are roughly 16,000 students at ECC (source: www.elgin.edu ), our sample of 100 is clearly less than 5% of the population. Also, np 0 (1-p 0 ) = 100(0.50)(1-0.50) = 25 > 10

Step 1 : H 0 : p = 0.5 H 1 : p ≠ 0.5

Step 2 : α = 0.05

Step 3 : We'll use StatCrunch.

Step 4 : Using StatCrunch:

StatCrunch calculation

Step 5 : Since P -value < α , we reject H 0 .

Step 6 : Based on this sample, there is enough evidence at the 5% level of significance to support the claim that the proportion of ECC students who support stem cell research is different from the Michigan poll.

One question you might have is, "What do we do if the conditions for the hypothesis test about p aren't met?" Great question!

A Binomial Refresher

The binomial probability distribution function.

The probability of obtaining x successes in n independent trials of a binomial experiment, where the probability of success is p, is given by

Where x = 0, 1, 2, ... , n

Using Technology to Calculate Binomial Probabilities

Here's a quick overview of the formulas for finding binomial probabilities in StatCrunch.

Click on > >

Enter n, p, the appropriate equality/inequality, and x. The figure below shows P(X≥3) if n=4 and p=0.25.

Hypothesis Testing Using the Binomial Distribution

Traditionally, about 70% of students in a particular Statistics course at ECC are successful. If only 15 students in a class of 28 randomly selected students are successful, is there enough evidence at the 5% level of significance to say that students of that particular instructor are successful at a rate less than 70%?

Step 1 : H 0 : p = 0.7 H 1 : p < 0.7

Step 4 : If we let X = the number of students who were successful, X follows the binomial distribution. For this example, n=28 and p=0.70, and we want P(X≤15). Using StatCrunch:

Step 5 : Since P -value < α (though it's very close), we reject H 0 .

Step 6 : Based on this sample, there is enough evidence at the 5% level of significance to support the claim that the proportion of students who are successful in this professor's classes are less than 70%. (Keep in mind that this assumes the students were randomly assigned to that class, which is never the case in reality!)

<< previous section | next section >>

Creative Commons License

Teach yourself statistics

Hypothesis Test for a Proportion

This lesson explains how to conduct a hypothesis test of a proportion, when the following conditions are met:

  • The sampling method is simple random sampling .
  • Each sample point can result in just two possible outcomes. We call one of these outcomes a success and the other, a failure.
  • The sample includes at least 10 successes and 10 failures.
  • The population size is at least 20 times as big as the sample size.

This approach consists of four steps: (1) state the hypotheses, (2) formulate an analysis plan, (3) analyze sample data, and (4) interpret results.

State the Hypotheses

Every hypothesis test requires the analyst to state a null hypothesis and an alternative hypothesis . The hypotheses are stated in such a way that they are mutually exclusive. That is, if one is true, the other must be false; and vice versa.

Formulate an Analysis Plan

The analysis plan describes how to use sample data to accept or reject the null hypothesis. It should specify the following elements.

  • Significance level. Often, researchers choose significance levels equal to 0.01, 0.05, or 0.10; but any value between 0 and 1 can be used.
  • Test method. Use the one-sample z-test to determine whether the hypothesized population proportion differs significantly from the observed sample proportion.

Analyze Sample Data

Using sample data, find the test statistic and its associated P-Value.

σ = sqrt[ P * ( 1 - P ) / n ]

z = (p - P) / σ

  • P-value. The P-value is the probability of observing a sample statistic as extreme as the test statistic. Since the test statistic is a z-score, use the Normal Distribution Calculator to assess the probability associated with the z-score. (See sample problems at the end of this lesson for examples of how this is done.)

Interpret Results

If the sample findings are unlikely, given the null hypothesis, the researcher rejects the null hypothesis. Typically, this involves comparing the P-value to the significance level , and rejecting the null hypothesis when the P-value is less than the significance level.

Test Your Understanding

In this section, two hypothesis testing examples illustrate how to conduct a hypothesis test of a proportion. The first problem involves a a two-tailed test; the second problem, a one-tailed test.

Sample Size Calculator

As you probably noticed, the process of testing a hypothesis about a proportion can be complex. Stat Trek's Sample Size Calculator can do the same job quickly and easily. When you need to test a hypothesis, consider using the Sample Size Calculator. The calculator is free. It can found in the Stat Trek main menu under the Stat Tools tab. Or you can tap the button below.

Problem 1: Two-Tailed Test

The CEO of a large electric utility claims that 80 percent of his 1,000,000 customers are very satisfied with the service they receive. To test this claim, the local newspaper surveyed 100 customers, using simple random sampling. Among the sampled customers, 73 percent say they are very satisified. Based on these findings, can we reject the CEO's hypothesis that 80% of the customers are very satisfied? Use a 0.05 level of significance.

Solution: The solution to this problem takes four steps: (1) state the hypotheses, (2) formulate an analysis plan, (3) analyze sample data, and (4) interpret results. We work through those steps below:

State the hypotheses. The first step is to state the null hypothesis and an alternative hypothesis.

Null hypothesis: P = 0.80

Alternative hypothesis: P ≠ 0.80

  • Formulate an analysis plan . For this analysis, the significance level is 0.05. The test method, shown in the next section, is a one-sample z-test .

σ = sqrt [(0.8 * 0.2) / 100]

σ = sqrt(0.0016) = 0.04

z = (p - P) / σ = (.73 - .80)/0.04 = -1.75

where P is the hypothesized value of population proportion in the null hypothesis, p is the sample proportion, and n is the sample size.

Since we have a two-tailed test , the P-value is the probability that the z-score is less than -1.75 or greater than 1.75. We use the Normal Distribution Calculator to find P(z < -1.75) = 0.04. Since the standard normal distribution is symmetric with a mean of zero, we know that P(z > 1.75) = 0.04. Thus, the P-value = 0.04 + 0.04 = 0.08.

  • Interpret results . Since the P-value (0.08) is greater than the significance level (0.05), we cannot reject the null hypothesis.

Note: If you use this approach on an exam, you may also want to mention why this approach is appropriate. Specifically, the approach is appropriate because the sampling method was simple random sampling, the sample included at least 10 successes and 10 failures, and the population size was at least 10 times the sample size.

Problem 2: One-Tailed Test Suppose the previous example is stated a little bit differently. Suppose the CEO claims that at least 80 percent of the company's 1,000,000 customers are very satisfied. Again, 100 customers are surveyed using simple random sampling. The result: 73 percent are very satisfied. Based on these results, should we accept or reject the CEO's hypothesis? Assume a significance level of 0.05.

Null hypothesis: P >= 0.80

Alternative hypothesis: P < 0.80

σ = sqrt[ P * ( 1 - P ) / n ] = sqrt [(0.8 * 0.2) / 100]

  • Interpret results . Since the P-value (0.04) is less than the significance level (0.05), we cannot accept the null hypothesis.

Module 8: Inference for One Proportion

Introduction to hypothesis test for a population proportion, what you’ll learn to do: conduct a hypothesis test for a population proportion..

This is a population density map of the United States of America

Contribute!

Improve this page Learn More

  • Concepts in Statistics. Provided by : Open Learning Initiative. Located at : http://oli.cmu.edu . License : CC BY: Attribution

Footer Logo Lumen Waymaker

steps in solving problems involving test hypothesis on the population proportion

User Preferences

Content preview.

Arcu felis bibendum ut tristique et egestas quis:

  • Ut enim ad minim veniam, quis nostrud exercitation ullamco laboris
  • Duis aute irure dolor in reprehenderit in voluptate
  • Excepteur sint occaecat cupidatat non proident

Keyboard Shortcuts

6a.2 - steps for hypothesis tests, the logic of hypothesis testing section  .

A hypothesis, in statistics, is a statement about a population parameter, where this statement typically is represented by some specific numerical value. In testing a hypothesis, we use a method where we gather data in an effort to gather evidence about the hypothesis.

How do we decide whether to reject the null hypothesis?

  • If the sample data are consistent with the null hypothesis, then we do not reject it.
  • If the sample data are inconsistent with the null hypothesis, but consistent with the alternative, then we reject the null hypothesis and conclude that the alternative hypothesis is true.

Six Steps for Hypothesis Tests Section  

In hypothesis testing, there are certain steps one must follow. Below these are summarized into six such steps to conducting a test of a hypothesis.

  • Set up the hypotheses and check conditions : Each hypothesis test includes two hypotheses about the population. One is the null hypothesis, notated as \(H_0 \), which is a statement of a particular parameter value. This hypothesis is assumed to be true until there is evidence to suggest otherwise. The second hypothesis is called the alternative, or research hypothesis, notated as \(H_a \). The alternative hypothesis is a statement of a range of alternative values in which the parameter may fall. One must also check that any conditions (assumptions) needed to run the test have been satisfied e.g. normality of data, independence, and number of success and failure outcomes.
  • Decide on the significance level, \(\alpha \): This value is used as a probability cutoff for making decisions about the null hypothesis. This alpha value represents the probability we are willing to place on our test for making an incorrect decision in regards to rejecting the null hypothesis. The most common \(\alpha \) value is 0.05 or 5%. Other popular choices are 0.01 (1%) and 0.1 (10%).
  • Calculate the test statistic: Gather sample data and calculate a test statistic where the sample statistic is compared to the parameter value. The test statistic is calculated under the assumption the null hypothesis is true and incorporates a measure of standard error and assumptions (conditions) related to the sampling distribution.
  • Calculate probability value (p-value), or find the rejection region: A p-value is found by using the test statistic to calculate the probability of the sample data producing such a test statistic or one more extreme. The rejection region is found by using alpha to find a critical value; the rejection region is the area that is more extreme than the critical value. We discuss the p-value and rejection region in more detail in the next section.
  • Make a decision about the null hypothesis: In this step, we decide to either reject the null hypothesis or decide to fail to reject the null hypothesis. Notice we do not make a decision where we will accept the null hypothesis.
  • State an overall conclusion : Once we have found the p-value or rejection region, and made a statistical decision about the null hypothesis (i.e. we will reject the null or fail to reject the null), we then want to summarize our results into an overall conclusion for our test.

We will follow these six steps for the remainder of this Lesson. In the future Lessons, the steps will be followed but may not be explained explicitly.

Step 1 is a very important step to set up correctly. If your hypotheses are incorrect, your conclusion will be incorrect. In this next section, we practice with Step 1 for the one sample situations.

Thank you for visiting nature.com. You are using a browser version with limited support for CSS. To obtain the best experience, we recommend you use a more up to date browser (or turn off compatibility mode in Internet Explorer). In the meantime, to ensure continued support, we are displaying the site without styles and JavaScript.

  • View all journals
  • Explore content
  • About the journal
  • Publish with us
  • Sign up for alerts
  • Open access
  • Published: 17 September 2024

Can carbon trading policy boost upgrading and optimization of industrial structure? An empirical study based on data from China

  • Daoping Chen   ORCID: orcid.org/0009-0005-8345-5434 1 ,
  • Haifeng Liao 1 &
  • Hong Tan 2  

Humanities and Social Sciences Communications volume  11 , Article number:  1234 ( 2024 ) Cite this article

Metrics details

  • Environmental studies
  • Social policy

Carbon trading policy is a major mechanism innovation based on the market to deal with climate change and reduce greenhouse gas emissions. As the scale of China’s carbon trading market gradually expands, the impact of carbon trading policy on the upgrading and optimization of industrial structures has attracted much attention. This paper depicts the upgrading of industrial structure through the advancement of industrial structure, and the optimization of industrial structure through the rationalization of industrial structure. Using panel data from 201 prefecture-level and above cities in China from 2004 to 2018, this study empirically investigates the impact and mechanism of carbon trading policy on the upgrading and optimization of industrial structure based on a double difference and mediation effect model. The research results show that carbon trading policy can generally promote the upgrading and optimization of industrial structures, but there are significant differences between promoting the upgrading and optimization of industrial structures. Mechanism analysis shows that carbon trading policy can promote the upgrading and optimization of industrial structure through technological innovation, and technological innovation has an intermediary effect. Heterogeneity analysis shows that there are significant differences between the eastern region and the central and western regions in carbon trading policy promoting the upgrading and optimization of industrial structure. Carbon trading policy is conducive to the upgrading of industrial structure in the eastern region, while they are conducive to the optimization of industrial structure in the central and western regions. In addition, it was found that there are significant differences in the promotion of the upgrading and optimization of industrial structure by carbon trading policy among cities with different levels of human capital, fiscal expenditure, foreign investment, and infrastructure. These conclusions can provide policy inspiration for high-quality green economic development, environmental policy formulation, industrial policy formulation, and urban resource allocation.

Similar content being viewed by others

steps in solving problems involving test hypothesis on the population proportion

The influence and acting pattern of China's national carbon emission trading scheme on regional ecologicalization efficiency of industry

steps in solving problems involving test hypothesis on the population proportion

The impact of intellectual property demonstration policies on carbon emission efficiency

steps in solving problems involving test hypothesis on the population proportion

Threshold effect of technological innovation on carbon emission intensity based on multi-source heterogeneous data

Introduction.

Carbon trading policy (CTP) refers to carbon emissions trading policy, which is an environmental regulation tool to solve global warming. Specifically, CTP is a policy measure used by the government to regulate the allocation and trading of total carbon emissions and carbon emission quotas (Zhang et al., 2014 ). China’s CTP includes six aspects: defining the scope of emission control, setting the total amount, allocating quotas, trading systems, reporting and verification mechanisms, and compliance and punishment mechanisms. CTP aims to create a free trading environment, fully leverage the role of the market in factor allocation, and ultimately achieve optimal allocation of carbon resources. The economic activities of human society are bound by the environment and in turn, affect the environment. Before the industrial revolution, the scale and scope of economic activities were small, and the impact of the environment on economic development and economic activities on the environment was inadvertently ignored. After the industrial revolution, the world seems to have found a fast path to economic development, but the problem of environmental pollution has become increasingly prominent.

In recent decades, environmental pollution has become a key factor restricting economic development. In the 1980s, the international community officially raised the issue of climate change for the first time, believing that the production of large amounts of greenhouse gases such as carbon dioxide from fossil fuels is the main cause of global climate change (Anjos et al., 2022 ; Jang et al., 2024 ). Only by working together can countries around the world jointly address this challenge. The market mechanism based on carbon emission trading has become a consensus as a new path for cooperation in solving greenhouse gas emissions problems. In 2011, China approved the pilot work of carbon trading in some provinces and cities, aiming to control greenhouse gas emissions by establishing a carbon trading market and conducting market trading based on greenhouse gas emission quotas. At present, the scale of quota trading volume in China’s pilot areas is second only to the European carbon market, and CTP has become an important means for China to promote enterprise emission reduction (Lv and Bai, 2021 ).

Industrial structure refers to the allocation and interdependence of resources between industries in a country or region during the process of social reproduction (Kuznets, 1957 ). It is generally believed that changes in industrial structure include two aspects: upgrading of industrial structure (UIS) and optimization of industrial structure (OIS) (Guan et al., 2022 ; Song et al., 2024 ). UIS refers to the process of transforming industrial structural systems from lower-level forms to higher-level forms. OIS refers to the coordination between various industries to maintain strong industrial structure transformation ability and good adaptability. Both UIS and OIS reflect the characteristics of changes in industrial structure. The difference lies in that UIS reflects the process of industrial structure evolution from lower to higher levels, such as the sequential transformation of industrial structure from labor-intensive to capital-intensive, and then to knowledge and technology-intensive, or the transformation from low value-added industries to high value-added industries, or the transformation from primary product industries to manufacturing intermediate and final product industries, which also means the continuous upgrading and innovation of traditional industrial production technology or the improvement of product technology content. OIS reflects the proportion balance and coordination degree between industries and reflects the efficiency of resource allocation, coordination, and utilization among industries. Under the constraints of productivity level and resource endowment, it is necessary to allocate production factors reasonably according to specific demand structures, achieve mutual coordination between industries, and maintain strong industrial structure transformation ability and good adaptability.

When the economy reaches a certain stage of development, UIS and OIS are crucial. Since the reform and opening up, relying on the development strategy of heavy industry first, China’s economy has made remarkable achievements in the world (Du et al., 2024 ). However, this mode of development has obvious characteristics of high pollution and extensive (Yu et al., 2020 ). High pollution not only aggravates the burden on the environment, but also makes the coupling degree between the input structure and output structure of factors low, resources are not effectively utilized, the transformation ability and adaptability of industrial structure are at a low level, and the economic growth is insufficient. Extensive development has resulted in a smaller share of industries with higher labor productivity, a lower level of industrial structure upgrading, and a lower quality of economic development. UIS and OIS are necessary processes for sustained economic growth and high-quality development in China (Xi and Zhai, 2022 ).

Can CTP, as an environmental regulatory tool, promote China’s UIS and OIS while reducing carbon emissions? UIS and OIS are obviously related to the environment. The reason why the current industrial structure is not optimized enough and needs to be upgraded is mainly because the industrial structure is highly polluted and extensive in economic development. An earlier study showed that the economic losses caused by environmental pollution accounted for at least 8 to 15% of the average annual GDP (World Bank report, 2007 ), which shows that there is still much room for improvement in UIS and OIS. CTP is directly aimed at the environment but may ultimately promote UIS and OIS, and UIS and OIS can better ensure the green nature of GDP. Under the incentive of CTP, enterprises can obtain new competitive advantages through the reallocation of resources, while enterprises at a competitive disadvantage may withdraw from the industry. The result of survival of the fittest makes the industry more coordinated to maintain strong industrial structure transformation ability and good adaptability. Some pollution-intensive enterprises may transfer to areas with low environmental standards in order to reduce environmental costs. This transfer not only increases the coordination between industries but also increases the adaptability between industries. CTP can also promote enterprises to develop advanced environmental protection technology through technological innovation to reduce costs, optimize internal production structure through advanced technology, and realize the upgrading of industrial structure. However, there are other possibilities. CTP has increased the product cost on the whole, and the enterprises in the industry are not adapted to the market at all, let alone the enhancement of conversion ability. Enterprises may also not have enough resources to mobilize for technological innovation, and the crowdsourcing transfer of many pollution-intensive enterprises may produce a synthetic fallacy. These circumstances may make CTP unable to promote UIS and OIS.

As the carbon trading market gradually expands, it is urgent to empirically understand the impact of CTP on China’s UIS and OIS. In relevant research fields, existing literature has mostly focused on the mechanism design of carbon trading, the emission reduction effects of CTP, and the impact of CTP on the economy. A small amount of literature has theoretically analyzed the impact of carbon trading environmental regulations on industrial structure, but there is almost no literature that studies the impact of China’s CTP on industrial structure from an empirical perspective and further explores the mechanism of this impact. Therefore, the research in this paper has important theoretical and practical significance.

Compared with the existing research, the contributions of this paper include the following three aspects. First, it is the first time to use the panel data of prefecture-level and above cities to study the impact of CTP on UIS and OIS. The sample size of panel data of cities at prefecture-level and above is larger, the data contains more information, and the practical characteristics of the impact of CTP on UIS and OIS can be more carefully captured. Secondly, it reveals the mechanism of the impact of CTP on UIS and OIS. In theory, both the “compliance cost hypothesis” and the “Porter hypothesis” indicate that CTP may promote UIS and OIS by promoting technological innovation, but this mechanism has not been verified empirically (Zhang and Duan, 2020 ; Porter and Linde, 1995 ). This study empirically found that CTP can promote UIS and OIS by promoting technological innovation. Thirdly, it expands the scope of research on the heterogeneity of the impact of CTP on UIS and OIS. The usual research on heterogeneity only discusses regional heterogeneity. This study not only studies regional heterogeneity but also studies the heterogeneity of urban characteristics in more detail. Characterized by human capital, financial expenditure, foreign investment, and infrastructure level, this study found that the role of CTP in promoting UIS and OIS is also different if the city characteristics are different.

Literature review

Economic development is faced with environmental constraints. The global climate warming caused by environmental pollution has external diseconomies. In order to achieve the goal of coordinating environmental protection and economic development, it is necessary to regulate economic activities based on environmental regulations. In economic activities, the irrational industrial structure or the low level of industrial operation may cause environmental problems. The government usually uses environmental regulation to regulate economic activities, hoping to promote UIS and OIS through environmental regulation, thus promoting economic growth and alleviating environmental pollution. As far as CTP is concerned, how to design the carbon trading mechanism, whether this mechanism design can reduce the level of carbon emissions, and what impact CTP will have on the economy are all issues worthy of attention. This paper will sort out these relevant documents. This paper aims to study the impact of CTP on UIS and OIS, and the mechanism of this impact. The literature in this area is the focus of this paper. The following is a literature review on these aspects.

The first is the literature on carbon trading mechanisms. The carbon trading mechanism is an environmental regulation based on market means to solve the problem of global climate change, and CTP is the core content (Shobande et al., 2024 ). The scope of the carbon trading mechanism is broader than that of CTP. Carbon assets were not commodities and had no significant development value. However, in order to address the issue of global climate change, countries jointly signed the Kyoto Protocol in 1997. According to the Kyoto Protocol, by 2010, the amount of six greenhouse gases emitted by all developed countries, including carbon dioxide, methane, etc., will be reduced by 5.2% compared to 1990. However, due to significant differences in energy utilization efficiency, energy structure, and adoption of new energy technologies between developing countries and developed countries, there are significant differences in emission reduction costs, which has led to the emergence of a carbon trading market (Oke et al., 2024 ). The carbon trading mechanism is a system that regulates the international carbon trading market, which includes mechanisms such as the clean development mechanism (CDM), joint implementation (JI), and emissions trading (ET).

The carbon trading mechanism regards carbon emission rights as a special commodity, and internalizes external costs through market-based means to guide enterprises to achieve emission reduction and promote low-carbon economic development (Chen and Mu, 2023 ). The key to the carbon trading mechanism is the allocation scheme of carbon emission rights among regions. One is to allocate carbon emission rights based on the current greenhouse gas emissions, the other is to allocate carbon emission rights based on the historical cumulative carbon emissions, and the other is to allocate carbon emission rights based on the carbon capital stock (Peng et al., 2023 ). However, no matter which allocation scheme is adopted, there may be mismatches. The mismatch of carbon emission rights may lead to adverse selection of enterprises. In order to eliminate the adverse selection of enterprises’ emission reduction from the mechanism design, it is possible to achieve better allocation efficiency by introducing the auction-paid allocation criteria into the carbon trading market (Chen et al., 2023 ). Zhou et al. ( 2021 ) believed that carbon emission quotas should be determined according to the impact of the carbon trading mechanisms on the competitiveness of different industries. Wang et al. ( 2024 ) believe that China’s carbon trading market has played a significant role in achieving emission reduction and environmental goals. In the future, we should speed up the improvement of carbon trading-related legislation, develop a multi-level carbon trading market, and pay attention to preventing the risk of quota overrun. In the context of the development of economic integration, the design of a cross-regional carbon emission coordinated governance mechanism has also received attention (Xie et al., 2019 ). At the micro level, the household carbon emission reduction incentive mechanism (Jia, 2023 ) and the establishment of an individual carbon trading market (Uusitalo et al., 2022 ) were included in the research horizon.

The second is the literature on the emission reduction effect of CTP. Generally speaking, the implementation of economic policies is usually affected by various external factors, and the policy effect is often uncertain. How about the emission reduction effect of CTP? At the initial stage of China’s carbon trading market pilot, scholars mostly focused on qualitative research, mainly involving the construction of a CTP performance evaluation index system and the practical problems in the implementation of CTP (Wu et al., 2016 ). With the continuous development of China’s carbon market, the research on CTP has begun to be quantitative, and this kind of research mainly focuses on the evaluation of the emission reduction effect of CTP. From different macro and micro levels, some scholars have empirically found that CTP has significant emission reduction effects and regional heterogeneity (Tan et al., 2022 ; Song et al., 2023 ). Liu et al. ( 2023 ) found that CTP can significantly improve the level of industrial carbon productivity, and can produce significant energy structure optimization effects. Fu ( 2024 ) believed that although CTP has significantly reduced carbon emissions and carbon intensity and has a significant emission reduction effect, its role in promoting carbon emission reduction is limited, and the market mechanism measured by the carbon price and market liquidity has no significant emission reduction effect. The development of some carbon markets in China is not perfect, the operation and pricing mechanism of the carbon market is not completely reasonable (Lin and Huang, 2022 ), the instability of carbon prices in the carbon market and the lack of liquidity of carbon trading products (Lyu et al., 2020 ; Lin and Jia, 2019 ), and a series of problems may weaken the positive impact of CTP in achieving the minimum social cost reduction. But on the whole, the emission reduction effect of CTP exists.

The third is the literature on the impact of CTP on the economy. CTP is an environmental regulation tool based on the property rights theory of the new institutional economics and taking carbon emissions trading as the core by means of marketization. Therefore, in addition to directly studying the impact of CTP on the economy, scholars have also studied the impact of the carbon emissions trading mechanism and environmental regulation on the economy. Wang et al. ( 2022 ) believe that CTP has significantly promoted the high-quality development of the economy, and there are significant regional differences in this promotion. Liu and Liu ( 2023 ) found that CTP has significantly promoted the innovative activities of enterprises to explore new knowledge, and the carbon quota allocation method has an important impact on the innovative activities of enterprises. The adoption of the intensity of the carbon quota allocation method is more conducive to the breakthrough innovation of enterprises, while the total carbon quota allocation method is more conducive to the progressive innovation of enterprises. Zhu et al. ( 2019 ) believe that CTP can have a positive impact on China’s economy by stimulating investment in low-carbon technology innovation, but this impact is heterogeneous at the micro level. Wang et al. ( 2024 ) constructed game models among manufacturers under different carbon trading models and found that when carbon quotas are within a certain range, various CTPs are beneficial to both original manufacturers and remanufacturers. This indicates that CTP has a positive incentive effect on micro-enterprises. Shi et al. ( 2023 ) studied the main exogenous shocks that caused China’s economic fluctuations under different carbon quota allocation modes and the mechanisms that affected China’s economic fluctuations and found that the factors that affected China’s economic fluctuations under different carbon quota allocation modes were different. Based on the research from the perspective of environmental regulation, the impact of environmental regulation on economic growth has a threshold effect on technological innovation (Wang, 2023 ; Chishti et al., 2023 ) . Only when human capital is at a high level can environmental regulation exert its positive economic growth effect (Liu and Pan, 2024 ). The coordination of environmental regulation policies, on the whole, has significantly promoted high-quality economic development, but there is significant heterogeneity (Kou and Shi, 2024 ). However, some scholars believe that the economic effect of CTP is weak, and the “strong Poter hypothesis” of CTP on total factor productivity has not been shown (Zhang et al., 2023 ), and it has not significantly promoted the low-carbon technological innovation of enterprises and the long-term value of enterprises (Wang et al., 2024 ).

The last is the literature on the impact of CTP on industrial structure. In essence, the impact of CTP on industrial structure also belongs to the category of economic impact, but considering the purpose of this paper, the literature on the impact of CTP on industrial structure is specially reviewed. An earlier study showed that under the constraints of a low-carbon economy, the extensive economic development model of high pollution is not enough to absorb the impact of emission reduction, and technological progress and structural transformation are crucial to the sustained and stable growth of China’s economy (Zhao et al., 2022 ). Harris and Sunley ( 2023 ) also believe that promoting industrial restructuring is the only way to achieve low-carbon development. The theoretical analysis believes that environmental regulation contributes to the adjustment of industrial structure, and the research on the mechanism of environmental regulation affecting industrial structure has formed three theoretical views. The first is the “compliance cost hypothesis “, which holds that environmental regulation makes enterprises pay extra costs to occupy the production and R & D funds of enterprises, resulting in the reduction of the production efficiency and operating performance of enterprises, and then affects the entry and exit of enterprises through the survival of the fittest, making the industry structure compulsory “cleaning” (Yang et al., 2012 ; Zhang and Duan, 2020 ). The second is the “pollution refuge hypothesis”, which holds that pollution-intensive enterprises often transfer to regions with low environmental standards or low intensity of environmental regulations in order to avoid environmental regulations or reduce environmental costs. This transfer will eventually make the industrial structure of a country or region adjust in the direction of rationalization (Millimeter and Roy, 2016 ; Dou and Han, 2019 ). The third is the “Porter Hypothesis”, which believes that appropriate environmental regulations can encourage technological innovation of enterprises. Enterprises can optimize their internal production structure by developing advanced technologies that can meet environmental requirements and reduce production costs, resulting in an innovation compensation effect (Porter and Linde, 1995 ). Du et al. ( 2021 ) found empirically that China’s environmental regulation policy can promote the upgrading of industrial structure through the reverse force mechanism, which seems to confirm the “compliance cost hypothesis”. However, some scholars believe that environmental regulation measures have not yet achieved the Potter effect in China, that is, environmental regulation has not achieved UIS and OIS through technological innovation (Nie et al., 2021 ).

As an environmental regulation tool, CTP has achieved positive results in promoting industrial structure adjustment (Chen et al., 2024 ). Jia et al. ( 2024 ) believe that changes in energy structure have driven the development of China’s industrial system towards the low-carbon direction. Therefore, the establishment of the carbon trading market is conducive to the regional transfer of high energy consumption and high-emission industries, thus increasing the coordination between industries and improving the transformation ability of industrial structure (Tang et al., 2016 ). Song and Kong ( 2018 ) found that carbon emissions trading volume has a significant positive impact on industrial structure changes, indicating that the development of the carbon emissions trading market can promote the optimization of regional economic structure. Liu and Cheng ( 2022 ) believe that carbon emissions trading can effectively promote the upgrading of regional industrial structure, but it is not conducive to the rationalization of regional industrial structure. The industrial structure optimization and upgrading effect of carbon emissions trading has obvious regional heterogeneity.

Through the aforementioned literature review, it was found that existing literature has conducted in-depth research on CTP from multiple perspectives, which can provide a reference for this article. However, the existing literature on the impact of CTP on industrial structure is not systematic and in-depth, especially the empirical research needs to be further deepened. For example, Du et al. ( 2021 ), Nie et al. ( 2021 ) and other studies involved industrial structure, but based on broader environmental regulations, there was no specific CTP, and the research conclusions were quite different. Two more relevant documents are the research of Song and Kong ( 2018 ), Liu and Cheng ( 2022 ). The former involves industrial structure but mainly focuses on economic structure, while the latter only uses provincial panel data to limit the scope and depth of the research. Based on the panel data of cities at the prefecture level and above, this study has more advantages in feature capture, mechanism recognition, and heterogeneity research.

Model and data

Benchmark model.

Based on the literature analysis mentioned above, it can be seen that CTP has a significant impact on industrial structure, but it is not entirely clear whether they have promoted UIS and OIS. The traditional view is that CTP, due to increasing corporate costs, has a negative impact on improving productivity and competitiveness, which may inhibit UIS and OIS (Dai et al., 2018 ; Zhang and Duan, 2020 ). The opposite of the Porter hypothesis suggests that CTP can encourage companies to engage in more innovative activities, which will increase productivity and offset the increase in costs caused by environmental protection, thereby enhancing the profitability of companies in the market and promoting UIS and OIS. There may also be another situation where companies pay additional costs to comply with CTP, which squeezes out production and research and development funds, leading to a decrease in production efficiency and operational performance. Such a portion of enterprises have been eliminated, and the industrial structure has been optimized. In addition, from the perspective of industrial transfer, CTP may also encourage pollution-intensive enterprises to transfer to areas with lower environmental standards in order to reduce environmental costs, which may lead to a rationalization of industrial structure.

Carbon trading entities include key emitting enterprises in industries such as electricity, steel, cement, construction, papermaking, and petrochemicals. CTP may achieve UIS and OIS through mechanisms such as cost constraints, innovation incentives, factor substitution, and consumption upgrading. CTP significantly increases the carbon emission cost of high-carbon industries, and low-carbon industries will gradually replace some of their shares due to their cost advantages. This will force high-carbon industries to carry out energy-saving and emission-reduction transformation, thereby promoting overall UIS and OIS. CTP can encourage enterprises to rationally allocate resources in research and development and operation, strengthen the cultivation of technological research and innovation capabilities, increase profits and enhance core competitiveness by selling remaining carbon quotas, and ultimately achieve UIS and OIS (Zhou and Wang, 2022 ). CTP can also optimize industrial structure through factor substitution. On the one hand, when a company reduces the use of traditional carbon-containing resources, it will inevitably reduce the market’s consumption and demand for such mineral resources, thereby easing the pressure on their mining upstream of the industrial chain; On the other hand, market-oriented carbon prices and quota trading mechanisms change the energy consumption structure of emission control enterprises by influencing their factor inputs, thereby promoting the green transformation of high-emission enterprises. Consumption upgrading may also be a mechanism by which CTP promotes UIS and OIS. Consumption upgrading promotes the flow of funds into energy-saving industries, and under the multiplier effect of funds, the industrial structure develops towards rationalization (Zhao et al., 2022 ).

In order to examine the impact of CTP on UIS and OIS, and to answer whether CTP can promote UIS and OIS, this paper uses the dual-difference (DID) model for empirical research. The DID model can obtain the net effect of policy implementation through the difference in time trend before and after policy implementation and the difference of policy implementation between the experimental group (pilot area) and the control group (non-pilot area) after effectively removing the unobservable heterogeneity factors. This method is a “quasi-natural experiment” method (Angrist and Pischke, 2018 ). Specifically, the cities under the jurisdiction of the pilot provinces are taken as the experimental group, and the other cities are taken as the control group. The fixed effects are estimated by setting the interactive dummy variables of whether the policy occurs or not. This design can not only alleviate the bias caused by missing variables to a certain extent but also effectively avoid endogenous problems caused by reverse causality, so as to more accurately estimate the net effect of policy implementation (Lv and Bai, 2021 ). The benchmark empirical model of this paper is set as follows:

Where i and t represent cities and years, respectively. The variable Upgrade i,t represents the level of UIS and OIS. treat i is a virtual variable of the city, with a value of 1 or 0. The variable post t is a dummy variable of time. If t is the implementation of the policy in 2011 and later, the value post t is 1, and the value of other years is 0. X i,t are control variables, which refer to other important factors affecting UIS and OIS besides CTP. η t is the time-fixed effect, μ i is the urban fixed effect that does not change with time, and ε i,t is the random error term. The coefficient β of the interaction term treat × post is the focus of the paper. It reflects the net effect of CTP on the optimization and upgrading of the regional industrial structure after the double difference.

Variable selection

Explained variable.

Upgrade is the dependent variable, representing the levels of UIS and OIS. UIS is measured by the advancement of industrial structure, and OIS is measured by the rationalization of industrial structure (Lin and Liao, 2023 ).

The variable SA represents the level of the advancement of industrial structure, defined as the product of the proportion of output in each industrial sector and labor productivity (Liu et al., 2008 ). The specific formula is as follows:

Where m represents the three major industries, with values ranging from 1 to 3. Y represents total output, LP labor productivity. The larger SA , the higher the UIS level, while the smaller SA , the lower the UIS level. Considering that the labor productivity LP in formula (2) has dimensions and the proportion of output value is a dimensionless index, it needs to be standardized. The formula is as follows:

Where \(L{P}_{i,m,t}^{N}\) represents the standardized labor productivity of the m industry after the completion of industrialization. The meaning of LP i,m,t is the same as before. LP mb is the labor productivity of m industry at the beginning of industrialization, and LP mf is the labor productivity of m industry at the completion of industrialization.

The variable SR represents the level of the rationalization of industrial structure. Under the constraints of productivity level and resource endowment, it is necessary to allocate production factors reasonably according to the specific demand structure to achieve mutual coordination among industries to maintain strong industrial structure transformation ability and good adaptability. Therefore, the coupling degree between the input structure and the output structure is crucial, which reflects the rationalization level of the industrial structure. This coupling degree is usually measured by the structural deviation degree. However, one disadvantage of the structural deviation degree is to treat the importance of each industry in the economy equally, and it may be more common to not consider the unbalanced phenomenon in the economy. For this reason, some researchers introduced the Theil index into the structural deviation degree to measure SR (Gan et al., 2011 ). This not only considers the coupling relationship between the input structure and the output structure, but also considers the unbalanced phenomenon in the economy. This study follows this approach, and the specific formula is as follows:

Where y i,m,t represents the proportion of the total output of i city m industry in year t to the gross regional product and L i,t represents the proportion of the employees in the total employment of i city in t year. If SR is 0, it indicates that the industrial structure has achieved an equilibrium state. If it is not 0, it indicates that the industrial structure deviates from the equilibrium state. The smaller SR value, the smaller the deviation between the industrial structure and the equilibrium state, and the higher the OIS. SR is an inverse indicator for OIS.

Explanatory variable

The explanatory variable is CTP, represented by treat ×  post . It is a dummy variable with 2011 as the point of policy impact. If a city is affected by CTP in 2011 or later, then treat × post =1, otherwise it is 0.

Control variable

In the empirical model (1), X represents a series of control variables, and λ is the coefficient of each control variable. The selection and measurement of control variables refer to relevant literature and consider the supply and demand factors that drive UIS and OIS (Lyu et al., 2023 ; Pan et al., 2023 ). Six control variables are selected in this study, which are: human (human capital), expressed by the proportion of the number of students in higher education in the total urban population; gov (government expenditure), expressed by the proportion of government public expenditure in urban GDP; pgdp (level of economic development) is expressed by the proportion of urban GDP to the total urban population; urban (urbanization level), expressed as the logarithm of the total urban population divided by the urban area; fdi (foreign investment) is expressed by the proportion of the total amount of FDI actually utilized to the urban GDP; instr (infrastructure) is expressed by dividing the urban road area by the total urban population. Among them, human , gov , fdi , and instr are also used to analyze the heterogeneity of urban characteristics. The details of each variable definition are presented in Table 1 .

Intermediary variable

Referring to other relevant studies (Hayes., 2009 ; Ma et al., 2024 ), this study uses a mediation effect model to identify the mechanism by which CTP affects UIS and OIS. Patent (technological innovation) is used as a mediator variable, measured by the number of urban patent applications (Liu et al., 2023 ). The measurements for all variables are presented in Table 1 .

Data source and description statistics

The panel data of 201 prefecture-level and above cities in China (including 33 pilot cities) from 2004 to 2018 were selected as the research samples, with a sample size of 3015. The data were sourced from the China Urban Statistical Yearbook and some prefecture-level city statistical annual reports, and all value variables were processed with 2004 as the base period (Brandt et al., 2012 ). The descriptive statistics of each variable are shown in Table 1 .

Benchmark model estimation results and robustness test

Estimation results of the benchmark model.

Table 2 shows the estimated results of model (1). Columns (1)–(3) in Table 2 reflect the estimated results of the impact of CTP on UIS. When no control variables are added, the coefficient of the CTP variable treat × post is 0.178, which is significant at the 1% statistical level; After adding the control variable, the coefficients of treat  ×  post are 0.202 and 0.185, respectively, under the two different conditions of fixed individuals or fixed time, which are significant at the statistical level of 1%, and the coefficient value increases. This shows that CTP has a significant positive impact on UIS, and the overall explanatory power of the model is enhanced after adding control variables. Therefore, CTP can promote UIS.

Columns (4)–(6) in Table 2 reflect the estimated results of the impact of CTP on OIS. It can be seen that the coefficients of treat × post are all negative and consistent with expectations, but the coefficients are not completely statistically significant. When no control variable is added, the coefficient of treat × post is negative 0.003, but it is not significant at the given statistical level; After adding the control variable, the coefficient of treat × post is negative 0.006, which is significant at the statistical level of 5%, and the absolute value of the coefficient increases when the individual and time are fixed at the same time. Although the estimated results are not perfect, the model still has some explanatory power. CTP can promote OIS to a certain extent, and the explanatory power of the model has increased after adding control variables.

From the perspective of the benchmark model estimation results, the coefficients of treat × post are all consistent with expectations. When individuals and time are fixed at the same time, the coefficients of treat × post are at least significant at the statistical level of 5% after adding control variables. Therefore, in general, CTP can promote UIS and OIS, but there is a significant difference between promoting UIS and OIS. CTP is more conducive to promoting UIS, which may also be the practical characteristics of the impact of CTP on UIS and OIS.

What needs further explanation is why the impact of CTP on OIS is weaker than that on UIS. OIS involves the rational allocation of resources and the coordination among industries. China’s carbon trading market has not yet fully developed and matured. The incomplete market mechanism and imperfect legal system make the resource allocation in the pilot area unreasonable (Wang et al., 2024 ). In addition, there is a lack of awareness of cooperation among enterprises and a low degree of inter-industry correlation (Lin and Jia, 2019 ). In the process of industrial structure adjustment, the adverse effects of these factors have weakened the role of CTP in promoting OIS, and the offset of adverse effects has led to the weaker role of CTP in promoting OIS than in promoting UIS.

The estimated results of the control variables show that in terms of UIS, the coefficients of human , pgdp , urban and instr are significantly positive, while the coefficients of gov and fdi are significantly negative. In terms of OIS, the coefficients of human and fdi are significantly positive, while the coefficients of gov and pgdp are significantly negative. This also further reflects that there are differences between UIS and OIS.

Dynamic effect test

One prerequisite for using the DID model is that there is no significant difference between the experimental group and the control group before the implementation of the policy, that is, there is a parallel trend between the experimental group and the control group before the occurrence of the policy. Therefore, it is necessary to test the parallel trend of CTP affecting UIS and OIS. In addition, the above-estimated results reflect the average impact of CTP on UIS and OIS in the pilot area. Over time, the impact of the CTP pilot on UIS and OIS may change accordingly. Therefore, it is necessary to further investigate the dynamic effects of CTP to reflect the differences in the effect of the pilot policy in different time periods. Using the methods of Xu and Cui ( 2020 ) for reference, the following model (5) is constructed to test the dynamic effects of CTP:

Where, post 04 represents a time dummy variable. If it is in 2004, it takes a value of 1, otherwise it takes a value of 0. The remaining 13 times dummy variables, such as post 05, are all assigned this value and the values of other variables are the same as those of Eq. ( 1 ). The base year is 2010, the year before the implementation of CTP.

The value and test results of coefficient β can be obtained by estimating the model (5). Figure 1 shows the dynamic effect diagram of coefficient β change at 95% confidence. From Fig. 1 , it can be seen that the interaction coefficient β is not significant before and after the implementation of CTP, indicating that there is no significant difference between the experimental group and the control group. The parallel trend assumption of double difference is satisfied, and the above estimation of the model (1) is effective. Further, from Fig. 1a of the dynamic effect of CTP to promote UIS, it can be seen that the value of β coefficient began to be significant and gradually increased since 2013, which indicates that the impact of the CPT pilot on the industrial structure in 2011 lagged for two years, and the role of CTP in promoting UIS gradually increased. It can be seen from Fig. 1b of the dynamic effect of OIS that the value of β coefficient gradually becomes negative after 2014, which indicates that the inhibition effect of CTP on the deviation of industrial structure from the equilibrium state begins to appear, and the time lag period of CTP on OIS is longer. In general, the implementation of CTP has a more obvious role in promoting UIS than in OIS.

figure 1

Note: the vertical line in the figure represents the base year 2010. The x -axis represents the year, and the y -axis represents the value of the coefficient β . a and b , respectively, reflect the dynamic changes in β values when SA and SR are used as dependent variables.

Robustness test

Placebo test.

Sampling 1000 times from 201 cities, 33 cities were randomly selected as virtual pilot cities each time, and the remaining 168 cities were used as control cities. By re-estimating model (1), the kernel density distribution Figure of the two explained variables SA and SR can be obtained as shown in Fig. 2 . It can be seen from Fig. 2 that t -test values of most of the sampling estimates are between ±2, and most of the P- values are above 0.1, which indicates that CTP has no significant effect in the 1000 random samples, indicating that other unknown factors have a little causal relationship with the impact of CTP on UIS and OIS of the pilot cities.

figure 2

Note: this figure reflects the distribution of t -values in sampling estimation, where panel a represents the distribution of t -values when SA is the dependent variable, and panel b represents the distribution of t -values when SR is the dependent variable.

Propensity score matching-double difference test (PSM-DID)

According to the PSM-DID method, the common support hypothesis is first tested, and the results show that the hypothesis is satisfied, and then the kernel matching method is used for estimation. Figure 3 shows the density function of propensity scores before and after matching. It can be seen from Fig. 3 that after matching, the probability density of the tendency scores of the experimental group and the control group has been relatively close, and the matching effectiveness is good.

figure 3

Note: this figure reflects the distribution of propensity scores, where panel a represents the distribution of propensity scores before matching, and panel b represents the distribution of propensity scores after matching.

Further, columns (1) and (2) of Table 3 present the PSM-DID estimation results. It can be seen from Table 3 that the estimated results of PSM-DID are basically consistent with those of Table 2 , indicating that the model’s estimation is robust, which further supports the above empirical conclusion that CTP has promoted UIS and OIS.

Delete the sample value test for the pilot year

Delete the observations from all provinces in 2011 and re-estimate the model. The results are shown in columns (3) and (4) of Table 3 . It can be seen from this that the coefficient of interaction terms is still significant at the level of at least 5%, which again shows that the conclusion that CTP promotes UIS and OIS is robust.

Further analysis

Mechanism analysis.

This paper empirically finds that CTP can promote UIS and OIS. In order to lead the research to depth, it is necessary to further study the transmission mechanism behind this. This paper will further explore the transmission mechanism of CTP promoting UIS and OIS from the perspective of technological innovation. In theory, the “compliance cost hypothesis” and the “Porter hypothesis” both predict that CTP may promote UIS and OIS by promoting technological innovation. On the one hand, CTP makes enterprises pay extra compliance costs to squeeze out the production and R&D expenditure of enterprises. The lack of expenditure will affect the speed of technological innovation of enterprises. The conversion of competitive advantages and disadvantages may lead to the withdrawal of the enterprise or the entry of other enterprises, and the industrial structure will have to be adjusted compulsorily. On the other hand, CTP can change the industrial structure by encouraging technological innovation of enterprises and generating an innovation compensation effect. In reality, the mechanism design of the carbon trading market allows enterprises to have a certain amount of free emission quota, while allowing free transfer of emission rights on the premise of complying with the provisions of the law. For high-polluting enterprises, after consuming their own emission quotas, they also need to purchase the excess part in the carbon trading market, otherwise they will face economic penalties, which will lead to an increase in the production costs of enterprises. For enterprises with advantages in production technology and technology research and development, after the implementation of the policy, the surplus quota can be sold on the market to obtain profits. High-polluting enterprises under the pressure of cost are forced to make technological innovations to alleviate the pressure of emissions. Enterprises with technological and R & D advantages are encouraged by profits to further carry out production technology R & D to improve the level of technological innovation and obtain more surplus quotas (Cai and Ye, 2022 ).

In the empirical aspect, the existing research has focused on the impact of CTP on technological innovation and the impact of technological innovation on industrial structure but failed to combine CTP, technological innovation, and industrial structure to examine the mechanism of CTP promoting UIS and OIS. In terms of the impact of CTP on technological innovation, the existing research believes that the establishment of a carbon emission trading pilot has promoted the level of low-carbon technological innovation (Liu et al., 2015 ), CTP has promoted breakthrough innovation activities of enterprises (Liu and Liu, 2023 ), CTP has promoted low-carbon technological innovation investment (Zhu et al., 2019 ), and similar research also includes Jia et al. ( 2024 ). In terms of the impact of technological innovation on industrial structure, the existing research believes that UIS and OIS based on technological innovation is an important way of economic growth (You and Zhang, 2022 ), and technological innovation affects UIS and OIS through three driving forces of technological diffusion, product demand and factor allocation (Zou, 2024 ). Zhang and Liu ( 2022 ) believe that technological innovation has a significant role in promoting UIS and has a positive spatial spillover effect. Today, with the development of digital technology, digital technology integration and innovation will help o UIS and OIS for a long time (Wang et al., 2024 ).

On the basis of existing research, combining CTP, technological innovation, and industrial structure, empirical research on whether CTP promotes UIS and OIS through technological innovation is not only a test of theory but also a concern for reality. Using the method of Hayes ( 2009 ) for reference, build a mediation effect model including three models, and identify the aforementioned transmission mechanism through the overall judgment of the coefficient of the model interaction terms. The specific settings are as follows:

The meaning of each variable in the model is the same as before. The test steps and judgment rules of intermediary effect are as follows: The first step is to test the coefficient α 1 which represents the total effect of CTP. If α 1 is significant, continue; otherwise, stop testing. The second step is to test the coefficients θ 1 and ξ . If both are significant, then the indirect effect is significant, proceed to the fourth step; If at least one coefficient is not significant, proceed to the third step. The third step is to use the Bootstrap method for testing. If significant, the indirect effect is significant. This can proceed to the fourth step, otherwise the test will be stopped. Step four, test the coefficient γ 1 . If it is not significant, i.e., the direct effect is not significant, then there is only a mediating effect; If significant, that is, the direct effect is significant, proceed to the fifth step. Step five, see the symbols of θ 1 * ξ and γ 1 . If the symbols are the same, there is a partial mediating effect; If there is a different symbol, it belongs to the masking effect.

Table 4 reports the estimation and test results of the intermediary effect models (6), (7) and (8). Through these results, we can determine whether the variable Patent has an intermediary effect in CTP to promote UIS and OIS. If there is an intermediary effect, it can be considered that the mechanism of CTP promoting UIS and OIS through technological innovation is established.

First of all, we will examine whether there is an intermediary effect of technological innovation in promoting UIS through CTP. It can be seen from column (1) of Table 4 that the coefficient of the interaction item treat × post is 0.185 and is significant at the statistical level of 1%, indicating that CTP has a significant impact on UIS. It can be seen from column (3) that the coefficient of treat × post is 7.582 and is significant at the statistical level of 1%, indicating that CTP has a significant impact on technological innovation. It can be seen from column (4) that the coefficients of treat × post and the technological innovation variable Patent are 0.088 and 0.013, respectively, and both are significant at the statistical level of 1%, indicating that CTP and technological innovation variables have a significant impact on UIS. According to the judging rules for testing the intermediary effect, technological innovation has an intermediary effect in CTP to promote UIS. CTP can promote UIS by promoting technological innovation.

Then we will examine whether technological innovation has an intermediary effect in promoting OIS through CTP. It can be seen from column (2) of Table 4 that the coefficient of treat × post is negative 0.006 and is significant at the statistical level of 5%, indicating that CTP has a significant impact on OIS. The test results of column (3) show that CTP has a significant impact on technological innovation. It can be seen from column (5) that the coefficient of treat × post is negative 0.006 and significant at the statistical level of 5%, but the coefficient of technological innovation variable Patent is not statistically significant. According to the judging rules of intermediary effect, it can not be determined that there is an intermediary effect in technological innovation, but it can also not be determined that there is no intermediary effect in technological innovation. Therefore, further tests are needed. The bootstrap sampling method is used to test whether there is an intermediary effect. Through 500 bootstrap sampling, the 95% confidence interval is (0.007,0.013), which does not contain 0, and the probability value P of the two-tailed test is 0.000. It can be seen that technological innovation has an intermediary effect in the process of CTP promoting OIS, and CTP can promote OIS by promoting technological innovation.

To sum up, CTP can promote UIS and OIS. In terms of the promotion mechanism, CTP can promote the development of UIS and OIS by promoting technological innovation. Technological innovation has an intermediary effect.

Heterogeneity analysis

Heterogeneity means that some things are different in some characteristics. When studying the impact of one variable on another variable, further investigation of the heterogeneity of the impact after clarifying the impact relationship will help to understand the impact more deeply and carefully. This study found that CTP can generally promote UIS and OIS. However, due to significant differences in economic development level, resource endowment, industrial structure, and other aspects among different regions, these differences may lead to heterogeneity in CTP when promoting UIS and OIS. Capturing this heterogeneity through relevant data is not only the need of empirical research but also helpful to put forward targeted differentiation policy recommendations. The heterogeneity analysis based on regional and urban characteristics in this paper is a further deepening of the research on the impact of CTP on UIS and OIS.

Analysis of regional heterogeneity

Based on Jin and Xu ( 2024 ), this paper divides China into the Eastern region and the Central and Western regions. Therefore, the regional heterogeneity analysis model of the impact of CTP on UIS and OIS is constructed as follows:

Where Did is the interaction term treat in model (1). location k is a location level variable with a value of 1 or 0. k represents the city type, with a value of 1 or 2, where 1 represents the eastern city and 2 represents the central and western cities. The interaction coefficient β reflects the regional heterogeneity of the impact of CTP on UIS and OIS. The estimated results are reported in Table 5 .

From the coefficient of interaction item Did × location in Table 5 , it can be seen that CTP has significantly promoted UIS of the eastern developed cities (as shown in columns (1) and (2)), both with and without control variables. However, in central and western cities, the impact of CTP on UIS is not significant (as shown in columns (3) and (4)). The eastern developed cities have a high level of industrialization. After the implementation of CTP, the location advantages of technology and capital promote enterprises to further innovate technology, improve labor productivity, and then promote the industrial structure of the eastern developed cities to develop in an advanced direction. The proportion of industries with high energy consumption and high pollution in the central and western regions is still large. The implementation of CTP has put forward higher requirements for the level of pollution control technology in the central and western regions. The high cost of pollution control may have a restraining effect on the advanced development of the industrial structure.

It can also be seen from Table 5 that CTP has not significantly promoted OIS of the eastern developed cities (as shown in columns (5) and (6)). However, for central and western cities, the implementation of CTP can promote OIS (as shown in (7) and (8)). The reason for this situation may be that the industrial structure of developed cities in the eastern region is already relatively reasonable, and the effect of CTP on further rationalizing their industrial structure is relatively weak. However, for the central and western regions, due to the large space for further improvement in OIS, when there are new situations where dominant industries or new technology industries strengthen the degree of correlation between industries, CTP more clearly promotes OIS in the region.

Heterogeneity analysis on urban characteristics

After discussing regional heterogeneity, this paper further explores the urban characteristic heterogeneity of CTP to promote UIS and OIS. The analysis of urban characteristics heterogeneity is the refinement of regional heterogeneity analysis and is more detailed in perspective. Referring to Shi et al. ( 2018 ), the four variables of human , gov , fdi , and instr are used to describe the urban characteristics. Cities are divided into low-level and high-level categories according to the value of each variable. The classification rules are as follows: first, they are sorted according to the value of each variable from small to large, then they are divided into first-class groups, second-class groups, and third-class groups according to the value of each variable from small to large, and finally, the first-class groups are classified as low-level categories, and the second-class and third-class groups are classified as high-level categories. For example, according to the classification of human capital, cities will be divided into low human capital cities and high human capital cities; If classified by fiscal expenditure, cities will be divided into two categories: low fiscal expenditure cities and high fiscal expenditure cities, and the rest are the same. Group regression based on model (1) is conducted, and the results are shown in Tables 6 and 7 .

First, by comparing the coefficient of interaction item treat × post in the two columns of human variable in Tables 6 and 7 , it can be seen that in cities with high human capital, CTP has a more significant role in promoting UIS and OIS (the interaction coefficient is 0.225 and −0.012, respectively), which shows that human capital plays an important role in promoting UIS and OIS by CTP. UIS and OIS depend on advanced technology, and the development and acquisition of advanced technology have a certain threshold. Workers with higher education levels find it relatively easy to learn these technologies, while workers with lower education levels find it relatively difficult to master and use technologies in a short time.

Secondly, by comparing the coefficient of interaction item treat × post in the two columns of gov variable in Table 6 and Table 7 , it can be found that in cities with high fiscal expenditure, CTP has promoted UIS (interaction coefficient is 0.326), and in cities with low fiscal expenditure, CTP has promoted OIS (interaction coefficient is −0.008), This reflects that there are significant differences between fiscal expenditure policies and CTP in promoting UIS and OIS.

Third, by comparing the coefficient of interaction item treat × post in the two columns of fdi variable in Table 6 and Table 7 , it can be seen that compared with the cities with low foreign investment, CTP in the cities with high foreign investment has a smaller effect on promoting UIS and OIS (interaction coefficient: 0.146 is less than 0.225, and the absolute value of −0.008 is less than the absolute value of −0.011). The reason for this phenomenon may be the balance between the long-term and short-term benefits of foreign capital. Foreign capital is unwilling to invest in emissions reduction which will take a long time. Therefore, in cities with high levels of foreign investment, the effect of CTP to promote UIS and OIS has not been fully played. It may also be the quality problem of introducing foreign capital. Only by introducing high-quality and cost-effective foreign capital can it drive UIS and OIS under the guidance of CTP.

Fourth, by comparing the coefficient of treat × post in the two columns of instr variable in Table 6 and Table 7 , it can be found that compared with low-infrastructure cities, CTP in high-infrastructure cities has a greater effect on promoting UIS and OIS (interaction coefficient: 0.214 is greater than 0.176, and the absolute value of −0.006 is greater than the absolute value of −0.001). A city with better infrastructure is more conducive to the flow of capital, labor, and other factors of production, and the city’s scientific and technological strength may also be stronger. So, UIS and OIS are more likely to be realized under the guidance of CTP.

To sum up, in the process of CTP promoting UIS and OIS, there are significant differences in the size of the boosting effect due to differences in urban characteristics, which shows obvious heterogeneity based on urban characteristics.

Conclusions and policy implications

Conclusions.

Under the realistic background that China’s economy has entered a high-quality, green, and low-carbon development, this paper uses the panel data of 201 prefecture-level and above cities in China from 2004 to 2018 and empirically studies the impact of CTP on UIS and OIS based on the DID model and the intermediary effect model. The purpose is to empirically test the boosting effect and mechanism of CTP on industrial structure and to examine the heterogeneity of the boosting effect.

On the whole, CTP can promote UIS and OIS. But compared with promoting OIS, CTP is more helpful to promote UIS. After a variety of robustness tests, the conclusion is still valid. The mechanism analysis found that CTP can promote UIS and OIS by promoting technological innovation, and technological innovation has an intermediary effect in CTP promoting UIS and OIS. In the new context, technological innovation has become the key path of CTP promoting UIS and OIS.

Further, the heterogeneity analysis found that there are regional heterogeneity and urban characteristics heterogeneity in CTP to promote UIS and OIS. In terms of regional heterogeneity, it is found that CTP has promoted UIS in the eastern region, but the impact on UIS in the central and western regions is not significant. CTP has no significant impact on OIS in the eastern region but has boosted OIS in the central and western regions. In terms of the heterogeneity of urban characteristics, it is found that in cities with high human capital, CTP plays a more significant role in promoting UIS and OIS. CTP in cities with high fiscal expenditure can promote UIS, and CTP in cities with low fiscal expenditure can promote OIS. In cities with high foreign investment, CTP has less effect on promoting UIS and OIS. In high-infrastructure cities, CTP has a greater effect on promoting UIS and OIS.

Policy implications

First, in the high-quality and green development of the economy, China must fully leverage the decisive role of market mechanisms. the high-quality development of the economy requires the industrial structure to develop from low to high, and the industrial structure is more optimized and reasonable. How to optimize and upgrade without increasing the environmental burden is the key to the green development of the economy. In the past, the carbon emissions of various regions and industries were generally controlled and constrained by administrative means. The implementation of CTP introduced the market mechanism into the field of environmental protection and optimized the allocation of carbon emissions of enterprises by market means. The research results of this paper provide empirical evidence for the feasibility of high-quality green development of China’s economy and also provide empirical interpretation for the rationality of the direction of carbon trading marketization reform.

Second, in formulating environmental regulatory policies, the government should pay special attention to their guiding role in enterprise technological innovation. The inducement factors of enterprise technological innovation are diverse, and CTP is one of many factors. This study found that CTP promotes UIS and OIS by guiding the technological innovation of enterprises, and technological innovation plays an intermediary role. With the establishment of the carbon trading market, the green and low-carbon energy consumption of high-emission industries has an endogenous power, and the carbon market has given enterprises continuous innovation incentives. Therefore, when formulating environmental regulation policies, the government should firmly grasp the key of technological innovation and take whether the environmental regulation policies can guide enterprises to actively carry out technological innovation as an important consideration.

Third, when formulating industrial policies, the government should fully consider the regional heterogeneity of the impact of CTP on industrial structure. The regional heterogeneity of the impact of CTP on industrial structure requires the government to take full account of the different impacts of CTP on enterprises in different industries in the eastern central and western regions when formulating industrial policies. The government must formulate customized strategies for UIS and OIS and corresponding policies and measures according to the actual industrial development status and comparative advantages of different regions, and respect the differences of different regions in UIS and OIS.

Fourth, In the allocation of urban resources, the government must fully consider the heterogeneity of urban characteristics in the impact of CTP on industrial structure. In order to maximize the boosting effect of CTP on UIS and OIS, it is necessary to reasonably allocate various resources from the perspective of carbon. For example, the government can increase the financial expenditure to ensure low-carbon technology breakthroughs in cities with low and medium economic development, and then improve the energy conservation and emission reduction technology of cities; The government can encourage and attract high-quality green and low-carbon foreign investment, and then drive the development of green technology in cities.

Research prospect

Terms such as climate change, low-carbon living, low-carbon economy, and green development have only gradually appeared in people’s lives in recent decades, but when people feel it, climate problems have become very serious. CTP, as an environmental regulatory tool to address climate change, promote green development, and promote harmonious coexistence between humans and nature, will inevitably have an impact on industries in economic development. This article empirically studies the impact and mechanism of carbon trading policies on industrial structure. However, due to various circumstances, this study inevitably has limitations. Future research can be conducted from the following three aspects.

Firstly, measure the industrial structure using other methods and examine the impact of CTP on the industrial structure. At present, the measurement of UIS and OIS are based on the traditional division of three industries, and this study is no exception. The theoretical basis of this division fundamentally stems from the evolution law of industrial structure described by the early Petty-Clark law. However, with the rapid development of high-tech such as information technology, the scale and methods of human industrial activities have undergone tremendous changes. The use of industrial structure measurement methods that take into account these changes in future research will be an extension of this study.

Secondly, in mechanism analysis, more factors can be considered than just technological innovation, although technological innovation may be a key factor. This article mainly examines the mechanism of the impact of carbon trading policies on industrial structure from the perspective of technological innovation and does not involve other possible mechanism factors. Therefore, further research is needed to examine whether other factors have a mediating effect in promoting UIS and OIS through CTP.

Finally, this paper is only based on data from China, and in the future, a comparative study of the impact of CTP between countries on industrial structure can be conducted based on data from more countries. Climate issues are a global issue, and carbon trading involves global markets. Research based on a global perspective will make the research more comprehensive and also be a natural extension of this study.

Data availability

All data used in the study have been provided in the supplementary materials.

Angrist JD, Pischke JS (2018) Mostly harmless econometrics: an empiricist’s companion. Princeton University Press, Princeton

Google Scholar  

Anjos MF, Feijoo F, Sankaranarayanan S (2022) A multinational carbon-credit market integrating distinct national carbon allowance strategies. Appl Energy 319(1)):119181. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2022.119181

Brandt L, Johannes VB, Zhang YF (2012) Creative accounting or creative destruction? Firm-level productivity growth in Chinese manufacturing. J Dev Econ 97(2):339–351. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2011.02.002

Cai WG, Ye PY (2022) Does carbon emission trading improve low-carbon technical efficiency? Evidence from China. Sustain Prod Consum 29:46–56. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.spc.2021.09.024

Chen WQ, Liu YH, Liu Y (2024) Exploring the spatial spillover effects of climate mitigation policies on the upgrading of industrial structure: Evidence from 31 provinces of China. Environ Chall 16:100963. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.envc.2024.100963

Chen XQ, Ma CQ, Ren YS, Lei YT (2023) Carbon allowance auction design of China’s ETS: A comprehensive hierarchical system based on blockchain. Int Rev Econ Financ 88:1003–1019. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2023.07.053

Chen Y, Mu HZ (2023) Natural resources, carbon trading policies and total factor carbon efficiency: A new direction for China’s economy. Resour Policy 86:104183. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2023.104183

Chishti MZ, Nadia A, Calvin WH (2023) Exploring the time-varying asymmetric effects of environmental regulation policies and human capital on sustainable development efficiency: a province level evidence from China. Energy Econ 126:106922. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2023.106922

Dai Y, Li N, Gu RR, Zhu XD (2018) Can China’s carbon emissions trading rights mechanism transform its manufacturing industry? Based on the perspective of enterprise behavior. Sustainability 10(7):2421. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10072421

Dou JM, Han X (2019) How does the industry mobility affect pollution industry transfer in China: Empirical test on Pollution Haven Hypothesis and Porter Hypothesis. J Clean Prod 217:105–115. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.01.147

Du KR, Cheng YY, Yao X (2021) Environmental regulation, green technology innovation, and industrial structure upgrading: the road to the green transformation of Chinese cities. Energy Econ 98:105247. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2021.105247

Du WH, Wei Y, Naeem MA (2024) Solid mineral development and Chinese economic growth: role of technological advancement. Resour Policy 95:105139. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2024.105139

Fu XS (2024) Impacts of the pilot policy for carbon emissions trading on pollution reduction in China. J Clean Prod 6(12):142878. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2024.142878

CAS   Google Scholar  

Gan CH, Zheng RG, Yu XF (2011) An empirical study on the effects of industrial structure on economic growth and fluctuations in China. Econ Res J 46(05):4–16. http://qikan.cqvip.com/Qikan/Article/Detail?id=37714817

Guan S, Liu JQ, Liu YF, Du MZ (2022) The Nonlinear influence of environmental regulation on the transformation and upgrading of industrial structure. Int J Environ Res Public Health 19(14):8378. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph19148378

PubMed   PubMed Central   Google Scholar  

Harris JL, Sunley P (2023) Multi-system dynamics in regional path upgrading: The intra- and inter-path dynamics of green industrial transitions in the Solent marine and maritime pathway. Prog Econ Geogr 1(2):100005. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.peg.2023.100005

Hayes AF (2009) Beyond Baron and Kenny: statistical mediation analysis in the New Millennium. Commun Monogr 76(4):408–420. https://doi.org/10.1080/03637750903310360

Jang MC, Yoon S, Jung S, Min B (2024) Simulating and assessing carbon markets: application to the Korean and the EUETSs. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 195:114346. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2024.114346

Jia LJ, Zhang X, Wang XN, Chen XL, Xu XF, Song ML (2024) Impact of carbon emission trading system on green technology innovation of energy enterprises in China. J Environ Manag 360:121229. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2024.121229

Jia SB, Zhu XW, Gao X, Yang XT (2024) The influence of carbon emission trading on the optimization of regional energy structure. Heliyon 10(11):e31706. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.heliyon.2024.e31706

CAS   PubMed   PubMed Central   Google Scholar  

Jia ZJ (2023) What kind of enterprises and residents bear more responsibilities in carbon trading? A step-by-step analysis based on the CGE model. Environ Impact Assess Rev 98:106950. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eiar.2022.106950

Jin YS, Xu YS (2024) Carbon reduction of urban form strategies: regional heterogeneity in Yangtze River Delta, China. Land Use Policy 141:107154. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2024.107154

Kou P, Shi JH (2024) Dynamic evolution of China’s government environmental regulation capability and its impact on the coupling coordinated development of the economy-environment. Socio-Econ Plan Sci 91:101785. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.seps.2023.101785

Kuznets S (1957) Quantitative aspects of the economic growth of nations: II. Industrial distribution of national product and labor force. Econ Dev Cult Change 5(4):1–111

Lin BQ, Huang CC (2022) Analysis of emission reduction effects of carbon trading: market mechanism or government intervention? Sustain Prod Consum 33:28–37. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.spc.2022.06.016

Lin BQ, Jia ZJ (2019) What are the main factors affecting carbon price in emission trading scheme? A case study in China. Sci Total Environ 654(1):525–534. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2018.11.106

ADS   CAS   PubMed   Google Scholar  

Lin ZQ, Liao XC (2023) Synergistic effect of energy and industrial structures on carbon emissions in China. J Environ Manag 345:118831. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2023.118831

Liu BL, Ding CJ, Hu J, Su YQ, Qin C (2023) Carbon trading and regional carbon productivity. J Clean Prod 420:138395. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2023.138395

Liu HY, Pan HY (2024) Reducing carbon emissions at the expense of firm physical capital investments and growing financialization? Impacts of carbon trading policy from a regression discontinuity design. J Environ Manag 356:120577. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2024.120577

Liu JY, Liu X (2023) Effects of carbon emission trading schemes on green technological innovation by industrial enterprises: evidence from a quasi-natural experiment in China. J Innov Knowl 8(3):100410. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jik.2023.100410

Liu LW, Chen CX, Zhao YF, Zhao ED (2015) China׳s carbon-emissions trading: Overview, challenges and future. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 49:254–266. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2015.04.076

Liu MF, Cheng SJ (2022) Does the carbon emission trading scheme promote the optimization and upgrading of regional industrial structure? Manag Rev 34(07):33–46. https://qikan.cqvip.com/Qikan/Article/Detail?id=7107978289&from=Qikan_Search_Index

Liu W, Zhang H, Huang ZH (2008) Investigation on the height of China’s industrial structure and the industrialization process and regional differences. Econ Perspect 11:4–8. https://qikan.cqvip.com/Qikan/Article/Detail?id=28726309&from=Qikan_Search_Index

Liu YB, Lu F, Xian CF, Ouyang ZY (2023) Urban development and resource endowments shape natural resource utilization efficiency in Chinese cities. J Environ Sci 126:806–816. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jes.2022.03.025

Lv MC, Bai MY (2021) Evaluation of China’s carbon emission trading policy from corporate innovation. Financ Res Lett 39:101565. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2020.101565

Lyu JY, Cao M, Wu K, Li HF, Ghulam M (2020) Price volatility in the carbon market in China. J Clean Prod 255:120171. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.120171

Lyu YW, Wu Y, Zhang JN (2023) How industrial structure distortion affects energy poverty? Evidence from China. Energy 278:127754. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2023.127754

Ma LD, Xu WX, Zhang WY, Ma YA (2024) Effect and mechanism of environmental regulation improving the urban land use eco-efficiency: evidence from China. Ecol Indic 159:111602. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolind.2024.111602

Millimet DL, Roy J (2016) Empirical tests of the Pollution Haven Hypothesis when environmental regulation is endogenous. J Appl Econ 31(4):652–677. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.2451

MathSciNet   Google Scholar  

Nie X, Wu JX, Chen ZP, Zhang AL, Wang H (2021) Can environmental regulation stimulate the regional Porter effect? Double test from quasi-experiment and dynamic panel data models. J Clean Prod 314:128027. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.128027

Oke AE, Oyediran AO, Koriko G, Tang LM (2024) Carbon trading practices adoption for sustainable construction: a study of the barriers in a developing country. Sustain Dev 32(1):1120–1136. https://doi.org/10.1002/sd.2719

Pan XF, Wang MY, Li MN (2023) Low-carbon policy and industrial structure upgrading: based on the perspective of strategic interaction among local governments. Energy Policy 183:113794. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2023.113794

Peng W, Xin BG, Xie L (2023) Optimal strategies for production plan and carbon emission reduction in a hydrogen supply chain under cap-and-trade policy. Renew Energy 215:118960. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.renene.2023.118960

Porter ME, Linde C (1995) Toward a new conception of the environment-competitiveness relationship. J Econ Perspect 9(4):97–118. https://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdfplus/10.1257/jep.9.4.97

Shi DQ, Ding H, Wei P, Liu JJ (2018) Can smart city construction reduce environmental pollution. China Ind Econ 6:117–135. http://qikan.cqvip.com/Qikan/Article/Detail?id=7000675382

Shi W, Li W, Qiao FW, Wang WJ, An Y, Zhang GW (2023) An inter-provincial carbon quota study in China based on the contribution of clean energy to carbon reduction. Energy Policy 182:113770. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol

Shobande OA, Ogbeifun L, Tiwari AK (2024) Extricating the impacts of emissions trading system and energy transition on carbon intensity. Appl Energy 357:122461. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2023.122461

Song JR, Hu SG, Frazier AE, Wu S, Wang M (2024) Will industrial structure changes promote or reduce non-grain production? Evidence from the Yangtze River Economic Belt. J Clean Prod 446:142902. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2024.142902

Song ML, Zheng HY, Shen ZY (2023) Whether the carbon emissions trading system improves energy efficiency–Empirical testing based on China’s provincial panel data. Energy 275:127465. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2023.127465

Song XL, Kong CM (2018) Empirical analysis of the impact of China’s carbon trading market on regional economic structure. Macroeconomics 9:98–108. https://qikan.cqvip.com/Qikan/Article/Detail?id=676533224&from=Qikan_Search_Index

Tan XJ, Liu YS, Dong HM, Zhang Z (2022) The effect of carbon emission trading scheme on energy efficiency: Evidence from China. Econ Anal Policy 75:506–517. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2022.06.012

Tang WQ, Wu LB, Qian HQ (2016) From pollution-heaven to green-growth—impact of carbon-market relocation of energy-intensive-sectors. Econ Res J 51(06):58–70. https://qikan.cqvip.com/Qikan/Article/Detail?id=669232853&from=Qikan_Search_Index

Uusitalo V, Huttunen A, Kareinen E, Wright T, Valjakka M, Pitkänen A, Levänen J (2022) Using personal carbon trading to reduce mobility emissions: a pilot in the Finnish city of Lahti. Transp Policy 126:177–187. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tranpol.2022.07.022

Wang B, Gong SY, Yang Y (2024) Unveiling the relation between digital technology and low-carbon innovation: carbon emission trading policy as an antecedent. Technol Forecast Soc Change 205:123522. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2024.123522

Wang DY, Sun YW, Wang Y (2024) Comparing the EU and Chinese carbon trading market operations and their spillover effects. J Environ Manag 351:119795. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2023.119795

Wang F (2023) The intermediary and threshold effect of green innovation in the impact of environmental regulation on economic growth: evidence from China. Ecol Indic 153:110371. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolind.2023.110371

Wang K, Wu PY, Zhang WH (2024) Stochastic differential game of joint emission reduction in the supply chain based on CSR and carbon cap-and-trade mechanism. J Frankl Inst 361(6):106719. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfranklin.2024.106719

Wang LH, Wang Z, Ma YT (2022) Does environmental regulation promote the high-quality development of manufacturing? A quasi-natural experiment based on China’s carbon emission trading pilot scheme. Socio-Econ Plan Sci 81:101216. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.seps.2021.101216

World Bank report (2007) Cost of pollution in China: economic estimates of physical damages. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEAPREGTOPENVIRONMENT/Resources/China_Cost_of_Pollution.pdf

Wu R, Dai HC, Geng Y, Xie Y, Masui T, Tian X (2016) Achieving China’s INDC through carbon cap-and-trade: Insights from Shanghai. Appl Energy 184:1114–1122. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apenergy.2016.06.011

ADS   Google Scholar  

Xi B, Zhai PY (2022) Economic growth, industrial structure upgrading and environmental pollution: evidence from China. Kybernetes 52(2):518–553. https://doi.org/10.1108/K-02-2022-0279

Xie QW, Hu P, Jiang A, Li YJ (2019) Carbon emissions allocation based on satisfaction perspective and data envelopment analysis. Energy Policy 132:254–264. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2019.05.024

Xu J, Cui JB (2020) Low-carbon cities and firms’ green technological innovation. China Ind Econ 12:178–196. https://qikan.cqvip.com/Qikan/Article/Detail?id=7103689551

Yang CH, Tseng YS, Chen CP (2012) Environmental regulations, induced R & D and productivity: evidence from Taiwan’s manufacturing industries. Resour Energy Econ 34(4):514–532. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2012.05.001

You JM, Zhang W (2022) How heterogeneous technological progress promotes industrial structure upgrading and industrial carbon efficiency? Evidence from China’s industries. Energy 247:123386. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2022.123386

Yu YZ, Sun PB, Xuan Y (2020) Do constraints on local governments’ environmental targets affect industrial transformation and upgrading? Econ Res J 55(08):57–72. https://qikan.cqvip.com/Qikan/Article/Detail?id=7102913673&from=Qikan_Search_Index

Zhang D, Karplus VJ, Cassisa C, Zhang XL (2014) Emissions trading in China: progress and prospects. Energy Policy 75:9–16. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2014.01.022

Zhang HJ, Duan MS (2020) China’s pilot emissions trading schemes and competitiveness: An empirical analysis of the provincial industrial sub-sectors. J Environ Manag 258(15)):109997. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2019.109997

Zhang SQ, Liu DB (2022) Spatial pattern and inf1uencing factors of industrial structure advancement in China based on technological progress. Econ Geogr 42(05):104–113. https://www.jjdl.com.cn/CN/abstract/abstract55126.shtml

Zhang YX, Zeng SB, Wu QS, Fu JY, Li TP (2023) A study on the impact of the carbon emissions trading policy on the mining industry based on Porter hypothesis. Resour Policy 87:104349. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2023.104349

Zhao J, Avik S, Nasiru I, Wang YH, Murshed M, Abbasi KR (2022) Does structural transformation in economy impact inequality in renewable energy productivity? Implications for sustainable development. Renew Energy 189:853–864. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.renene.2022.03.050

Zhao ZY, Zhou SN, Wang SY, Ye C, Wu TL (2022) The impact of carbon emissions trading pilot policy on industrial structure upgrading. Sustainability 14(17):10818. https://doi.org/10.3390/su141710818

Zhou FX, Wang XY (2022) The carbon emissions trading scheme and green technology innovation in China: A new structural economics perspective. Econ Anal Policy 74:365–381. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2022.03.007

Zhou HJ, Ping WY, Wang Y, Wang YY, Liu KL (2021) China’s initial allocation of interprovincial carbon emission rights considering historical carbon transfers: program design and efficiency evaluation. Ecol Indic 121:106918. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolind.2020.106918

Zhu J, Fan Y, Deng X, Xue L (2019) Low-carbon innovation induced by emissions trading in China. Nat Commun 10:4088. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41467-019-12213-6

ADS   CAS   PubMed   PubMed Central   Google Scholar  

Zou TY (2024) Technological innovation promotes industrial upgrading: an analytical framework. Struct Change Econ Dyn 70:150–167. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.strueco.2024.01.012

Download references

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

School of Economics and Management, Chongqing Normal University, Chongqing, China

Daoping Chen & Haifeng Liao

College of Electrical Engineering and New Energy, China Three Gorges University, Yichang, China

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Contributions

The authors confirm their contribution to the paper as follows: study conception and design: Daoping Chen, Haifeng Liao, Hong Tan; methodology and model building: Daoping Chen, Haifeng Liao; analysis and interpretation of results: Daoping Chen, Haifeng Liao; software and writing-original draft: Haifeng Liao; validation and supervision: Daoping Chen; resources: Hong Tan. All authors reviewed the results and approved the final version of the manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Daoping Chen .

Ethics declarations

Competing interests.

The authors declare no competing interests.

Ethical approval

Ethical approval was not required as the study did not involve human participants.

Informed consent

No human participants were involved in the study. All authors listed have approved the attached manuscript.

Additional information

Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary information

Rights and permissions.

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International License, which permits any non-commercial use, sharing, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if you modified the licensed material. You do not have permission under this licence to share adapted material derived from this article or parts of it. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ .

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article.

Chen, D., Liao, H. & Tan, H. Can carbon trading policy boost upgrading and optimization of industrial structure? An empirical study based on data from China. Humanit Soc Sci Commun 11 , 1234 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41599-024-03739-2

Download citation

Received : 29 February 2024

Accepted : 02 September 2024

Published : 17 September 2024

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1057/s41599-024-03739-2

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

Quick links

  • Explore articles by subject
  • Guide to authors
  • Editorial policies

steps in solving problems involving test hypothesis on the population proportion

IMAGES

  1. SOLVING PROBLEMS INVOLVING TEST OF HYPOTHESIS ON POPULATION PROPORTION

    steps in solving problems involving test hypothesis on the population proportion

  2. SOLUTION: Solving problems involving test of hypothesis on population

    steps in solving problems involving test hypothesis on the population proportion

  3. Hypothesis Testing

    steps in solving problems involving test hypothesis on the population proportion

  4. SOLVING PROBLEMS INVOLVING TEST OF HYPOTHESIS ON POPULATION MEAN

    steps in solving problems involving test hypothesis on the population proportion

  5. SOLVING PROBLEMS INVOLVING TEST OF HYPOTHESIS ON POPULATION MEAN

    steps in solving problems involving test hypothesis on the population proportion

  6. Statistics and Probability Module 14: Solving Problems Involving Test

    steps in solving problems involving test hypothesis on the population proportion

VIDEO

  1. CLASSROOM OBSERVATION || SOLVING PROBLEMS INVOLVING TEST OF HYPOTHESIS ON POPULATION MEAN

  2. SOLVING PROBLEMS INVOLVING TEST OF HYPOTHESIS ON POPULATION PROPORTION

  3. G11 Statistic and Probability (Q4 W5) Solve Problems Involving test Hypothesis on Population Mean

  4. HYPOTHESIS TESTING FOR POPULATION PROPORTION

  5. Hypothesis Testing with Two Proportions

  6. SOLVING PROBLEMS INVOLVING TEST OF HYPOTHESIS ON POPULATION MEAN & PROPORTION :: Statistics & Prob

COMMENTS

  1. 3.4: Hypothesis Test for a Population Proportion

    H1: p ≠ 0.75. Step 2) State the level of significance and the critical value. This is a two-sided question so alpha is divided by 2. Alpha is 0.05 so the critical values are ± Zα/2 = ± Z.025. Look on the negative side of the standard normal table, in the body of values for 0.025. The critical values are ± 1.96.

  2. 8.8 Hypothesis Tests for a Population Proportion

    The p -value for a hypothesis test on a population proportion is the area in the tail (s) of distribution of the sample proportion. If both n× p ≥ 5 n × p ≥ 5 and n ×(1− p) ≥ 5 n × (1 − p) ≥ 5, use the normal distribution to find the p -value. If at least one of n× p <5 n × p <5 or n×(1 −p) <5 n × (1 − p) <5, use the ...

  3. 8.4: Hypothesis Test Examples for Proportions

    For the hypothesis test, she uses a 1% level of significance. Answer. Set up the hypothesis test: The 1% level of significance means that α = 0.01. This is a test of a single population proportion. \(H_{0}: p = 0.50\) \(H_{a}: p \neq 0.50\) The words "is the same or different from" tell you this is a two-tailed test. Calculate the distribution ...

  4. PDF STAT 201 Chapter 9.1-9.2 Hypothesis Testing for Proportion

    A Hypothesis is a proposition assumed as a premise in an argument. It's a statement regarding a characteristic of one or more populations. Hypothesis testing is a procedure based on evidence found in a sample to test hypothesis. The null hypothesis, , is a statement to be tested. The null hypothesis is a statement of no change, no effect or ...

  5. 8.15: Hypothesis Test for a Population Proportion (3 of 3)

    Step 2: Collect the data. Since the hypothesis test is based on probability, random selection or assignment is essential in data production. Additionally, we need to check whether the sample proportion can be np ≥ 10 and n (1 − p) ≥ 10. Step 3: Assess the evidence. Determine the test statistic which is the z -score for the sample proportion.

  6. PDF CHAPTER 8 Hypothesis Testing for Population Proportions

    The notation used for the null hypothesis and alternative hypothesis Try to understand the difference between the significance level and the p-value. They are both probabilities! (See pp. 360 and 362) Know the formula for the one-proportion z-test statistic Section 8.2 Hypothesis Testing in Four Steps

  7. Section 10.2: Hypothesis Tests for a Population Proportion

    Testing Claims Regarding the Population Proportion Using P-Values. In this first section, we assume we are testing some claim about the population proportion. As usual, the following two conditions must be true: np(1-p)≥10, and; n≤0.05N

  8. Hypothesis Test for a Population Proportion (1 of 3)

    Once we know that we are dealing with a single population proportion, we can conduct the hypothesis test. Recall that the first step of a hypothesis test is to determine the hypotheses. In the previous section, our hypotheses were in words. In this section, we use symbols. Recall that the symbol for the population proportion is p.

  9. Hypothesis Test for a Proportion

    Solution: The solution to this problem takes four steps: (1) state the hypotheses, (2) formulate an analysis plan, (3) analyze sample data, and (4) interpret results. We work through those steps below: State the hypotheses. The first step is to state the null hypothesis and an alternative hypothesis.

  10. PDF Quarter 4 Module 14: of Hypothesis on Population Proportion

    w important steps in order to arrive at the correct answer.Here are the five (5) steps in solving pro. ms for. test of hypothesis on the population proportion. STEP 1. HYPOTHESES: State the null and alternative hypotheses (either. a :

  11. Hypothesis Test for a Population Proportion (2 of 3)

    Our sample proportion was 0.02 above the population proportion from the null hypothesis. In a sample of size 500, we would observe a sample proportion 0.02 or more away from 0.84 about 22% of the time by chance alone. Step 4: State a conclusion. Again we compare the P-value to the level of significance, α = 0.05.

  12. PDF Quarter 4 Module 14: Solving Pr of Hypothesis on Population Proportion

    1. enumerate the steps in solving problems involving test of hypothesis on population proportion; and 2. solve problems involving test of hypothesis on the population proportion. What I Know Directions: Choose the best answer to the given questions or statements. Write the letter of your choice on a separate sheet of paper. 1.

  13. 8.7: Hypothesis Test of Single Population Proportion with Examples

    First, determine what type of test this is, set up the hypothesis test, find the p-value, sketch the graph, and state your conclusion. Answer. Since the problem is about percentages, this is a test of single population proportions. H0: p = 0.85. Ha: p ≠ 0.85.

  14. S.6 Test of Proportion

    The steps to perform a test of proportion using the critical value approval are as follows: State the null hypothesis H0 and the alternative hypothesis HA. Calculate the test statistic: z = p ^ − p 0 p 0 (1 − p 0) n. where p 0 is the null hypothesized proportion i.e., when H 0: p = p 0. Determine the critical region. Make a decision.

  15. Introduction to Hypothesis Test for a Population Proportion

    When we have real world data on population proportions we will have to learn when a situation calls for testing a hypothesis about a population proportion, conduct a hypothesis test and state a conclusion in context. We will interpret the P-value as a conditional probability in the context of a hypothesis test. We will then distinguish the ...

  16. Hypothesis Testing

    This statistics video tutorial explains how to solve hypothesis testing problems with proportions. It explains how to calculate the sample proportion and th...

  17. Hypothesis Tests for Population Proportions

    Revision notes on Hypothesis Tests for Population Proportions for the College Board AP® Statistics syllabus, written by the Statistics experts at Save My Exams.

  18. 6a.2

    6a.1 - Introduction to Hypothesis Testing ; 6a.2 - Steps for Hypothesis Tests; 6a.3 - Set-Up for One-Sample Hypotheses; 6a.4 - Hypothesis Test for One-Sample Proportion. 6a.4.1 - Making a Decision; 6a.4.2 - More on the P-Value and Rejection Region Approach; 6a.4.3 - Steps in Conducting a Hypothesis Test for \(p\) 6a.5 - Relating the CI to a Two ...

  19. 9.5: A Population Proportion

    In a hypothesis test problem, you may see words such as "the level of significance is 1%." The "1%" is the preconceived or preset \(\alpha\). The statistician setting up the hypothesis test selects the value of α to use before collecting the sample data. If no level of significance is given, a common standard to use is \(\alpha = 0.05\).

  20. Statistics and Probability Module: Solving Problems Involving Test of

    Although problem solving has steps, someone may have his/her own way or techniques of solving a problem. Meanwhile, in statistical analysis, there are steps that need to be followed in solving problems involving test of hypothesis on population proportion. The objective is for us to make a correct decision about the null hypothesis.

  21. 8.2: Hypothesis Testing of Single Proportion

    Either five-step procedure, critical value or p -value approach, can be used. 8.2: Hypothesis Testing of Single Proportion is shared under a license and was authored, remixed, and/or curated by LibreTexts. Both the critical value approach and the p-value approach can be applied to test hypotheses about a population proportion.

  22. PDF Quarter 4 Module 8: Solving Problems Involving Test of Hypothesis on

    raw cornstarch diet has a mean glucose level of 135 with a standard d. = 25 = 0.10Step 1: State the null and alternative hypothes. = 120 : ≠ 120Step 2: Determine the test statistic, then compute its value.= 24Since it is the population mean being tested, the population st. is unknown, a.

  23. Stat and Prob Q4 Mod14 Solving Problems Involving Test of Hypothesis on

    Meanwhile, in statistical analysis, there are steps that need to be followed in solving problems involving test of hypothesis on population proportion. The objective is for us to make a correct decision about the null hypothesis. It is whether we can confidently say that the change in our data is real, definite, and not attributed by chance.

  24. Can carbon trading policy boost upgrading and optimization of

    If significant, the indirect effect is significant. This can proceed to the fourth step, otherwise the test will be stopped. Step four, test the coefficient γ 1. If it is not significant, i.e ...

  25. 29: Hypothesis Test for a Population Proportion Calculator

    hypothesis test for a population Proportion calculator. Fill in the sample size, n, the number of successes, x, the hypothesized population proportion p0 p 0, and indicate if the test is left tailed, <, right tailed, >, or two tailed, ≠ ≠. Then hit "Calculate" and the test statistic and p-Value will be calculated for you. Scientific Calculator.